Comparative Behavior
Week 1: General Introductions & Syllabus
This week was primarily introductions from other classmates and the professor. Some discussion included expectations and what the class would look like.
Syllabus
Week 2: Intro to Comparative Political Behavior
Anderson, Christopher J. 2009. “Interaction of Structures and Voter Behavior.” OHPB CH. 31: 589-609.
Bumper Sticker: Rules & context influence and are influenced by behaviour! (British spelling)
Abstract: This article discusses and reviews the growing literature on the nexus of macro-level structures and individual behaviour that some studies are a part of. It looks at the effects that macro-level institutions and contexts have on citizen behaviour, along with how political institutions and the environment where citizens form opinions and act, help in moderating the effects of individual-level factors on citizen behaviour. The modelling structures and behaviour, effects of structures on voter behaviour, and the interactions of structures and behaviour in research on economic voting are some of the topics covered in the article.
Outline:
Does x cause behaviour y? It depends!
- Example: Does institutional performance affect people’s sense of whether their political system is legitimate?
- Answer: The impact of corruption on system support is conditional on whether citizens are supporters of the incumbent government.
- Studies are getting better at using institutions and context to predict the effects of citizen behaviour.
- Example: Does institutional performance affect people’s sense of whether their political system is legitimate?
Comparative study of structures and behaviour = citizens in context
Context and behaviour intimately connected by:
- Formal and informal rules; people’s preferences, attitudes, and behaviour affect the establishment and functioning of rules
- Citizens are exposed to variable social, political, and economic environments that they are supposed to understand, interpret, and sometimes shape
Advances in surveys, replication, and computing have allowed for cross-national and multi-level research into behaviour
1980s and 1990s renewed focus on institutional questions across polysci that could be tested, as well as interest in developing contextual theories of political behaviour
Comparative study of behaviour politics has investigated macro-level contexts/structures:
Institutions
Structural conditions
Interaction between structures and behaviour presumes several things:
- Politics is about the interaction of people’s values and the rules and conditions that govern the implementation of those values
- The rules and realities in which citizens make choices are themselves a function of people’s values
- “Put another way: contexts are critical for understanding the decisions people make because they affect different people differently, and people’s decisions, in turn, shape the nature, shape, and stability of these contexts” (678).
Common approach assumes that context shapes behaviour; assumes behaviour to be DV and that it is exogenous and stable
Do institutions have direct effects on behaviour?
- Voting example: structures can affect voters directly, indirectly, and interactively (or contingently)
- Direct: rational choice theory; individuals weigh costs and benefits of voting and act accordingly
- Indirect: behaviours of elites within electoral rules empower or constrain citizen choices; structures have consequences but these consequences have secondary (or indirect) effects on behaviour
- Contingent: effect of some structural feature strengthened or weakened, depending on presence of some 3rd variable; the turnout gap between individuals with many and few resources is particularly pronounced in countries where the cost of voting is high
- Voting example: structures can affect voters directly, indirectly, and interactively (or contingently)
{INSERT PHOTO HERE}
- Recent studies have looked at how the nature of a country’s representative structures interacts with the willingness of voters to punish governments for bad economic performance
- Bad economy impact hinges on ability of voters to hold gov’t responsible
- Institutions can hamper this ability of voters to reward or punish gov’ts
- Clarity of responsibility also varies over time within (and across) countries b/c of election outcomes that change bargaining power and reshape context
- Also contingent upon credible alternatives for voters to vote into office
- Interactions of vote choice and structures in research on legitimacy
What role do institutions play in moderating sense of loss or victory citizens feel?
- Institutions shape the responses of winners and losers; citizen attitudes toward democratic institutions shaped by country’s political context
- “At the end of the day, what is particularly noteworthy about cross-level investigations of behavioural politics is that they hold the promise of producing a more nuanced and contextualized understanding of political life by connected hitherto unconnected streams of scholarship in the areas of institutions, political economy, policy, and behaviour and allowing us a better and more complex empirical and theoretical handle on the hows and whys of citizen politics” (690).
Chong, Dennis. 2013. “Degrees of Rationality in Politics.” Ch. 4 in Leonie Huddy, David O. Sears and Jack S. Levy, Eds., The Oxford Handbook of Political Psychology, 2nd edition. Oxford University Press
NEED TO UPDATE!
Week 3: Political Beliefs/Political Decision-Making
Converse, Philip E. 2006 [1964]. “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics.” Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 18(1): 1-74
Normative question:
Does the citizenry have the “capacity” to participate in democracy? Concern the age-old question of the demos’ potential to access information and process it in a way that would be individually coherent in election expressions. Converse’s (1964) “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics” marks a turning point since it can quantitatively/statistically demonstrate
democracy defenders’ worst fears: the mass public competence for a normative functioning of democracy is blight. This question has also been approached with similar results by Lipmann (1922), “Public Opinion” and Schumpeter (1950), “Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy” (see also Bennett, 2006, “Democratic Competence, Before Converse and After”).
Bumper Sticker:
Mass Public: Ideologically Innocent
DV:
Degree of Belief System Coherence (Individual) (a continuum)
IV:
Level of Constrained Idea-Elements (a continuum)
Data:
Converse stipulates that the degree of coherence of the mass public belief system is contingent on the level of constraints of the idea-elements populating a belief system: the more constrained, the more coherent. This, in turn, predicts a degree of capacity to participate in democracy according to one’s self-assessed ideological placement. Idea-elements are mainly constrained by the transmission of information and its digestibility. For this reason, Converse finds that 15% of the population is deemed ideologue or near-ideologue (possessing a coherent belief system = elite political actors). In contrast, the remaining 85% (the masses) float between having a particular interest (issue public) or having no idea. If ideology is not driving most of the public’s opinion incentive, what is? Converse suggests that “visible” social groupings serve as a stable heuristic informing public opinion: party ID (.70) has more bearing than policies, but policies concerning visible groups (school desegregation .45) have more bearing than regular policies (government and housing .28). This “ideology by proxy” might produce idiosyncratic outcomes as well: the working man associating with Socialists against the rich but against government reigning of private enterprise’s provision of public goods.
PICTURE HERE
Acquiring and processing information is contingent on education. Education is more prevalent in higher strata of society (Lipset, 1959, “Social Requisite of Democracy”).
PICTURE HERE
Interesting proposition: “The net result of these circumstances is that the elites of the leftist parties enjoy a”natural” numerical superiority, yet they are cursed with a clientele that is less dependable or solid in its support. The rightist elite has a natural clientele that is more limited but more dependable.”
Huckfeldt, Robert. 2009. “Information, Persuasion and Political Communication.” OHPB. Ch. 6: 100-122.
Bumper Sticker:
Social networks allow us to rethink and re-conceptualize the role of groups in mass politics and public opinion.
Abstract
This article presents a survey and interpretation of the contributions made by #network #theories on the study of citizens and democratic policies. The article serves as an overview of the topic. It begins by locating the network research within the rich substantive and theoretical tradition of individually and #group-based studies of #electoral #politics and #public #opinion . It addresses some methodological issues in the study of political information #networks. The article ends with the discussion of theoretical and substantive insights that were generated in several studies, such as the study of communication and persuasion among citizens.
Research Question:
What is network analysis? What are the theoretical and substantive insights that we can derive from it, particularly regarding the study of communication and persuasion among citizens? What are some of the methodological issues of network analysis?
Summary/Theory/Argument:
The author sets out to analyze the contribution of network theories, which have provided us the ability to analyze citizen and democratic politics from across the micro-macro spectrum. Network theories draw on the importance of groups, communities, and political information networks among and between individuals (Downs 1957) while incorporating a conceptual apparatus that extends far past the traditional notions of primary groups, organizations, and societal groups in order to define the relationships that exist among individuals at multiple levels of analysis. Despite its advantages, there are still some methodological issues with network analysis.
Data/Methods:
It is a literature review so no real data/methods.
Findings:
What is network analysis and how does it fit into the existing literature on the study of individuals and groups?
- Network studies can be seen as a particular species within a larger genus—as one type of a contextual analysis of politics (Knoke 1990)
- networks are formed at the complex intersection between individual preference, individual engagement, and individual location within particular contexts.
- Eulau (1986) and Przeworski and Teune (1970) define contextual factors in terms of the aggregation of individual characteristics that affect individuals through processes of social interaction.
- Network Studies diverge from contextual studies in their effort to incorporate a direct mapping for the particular patterns of recurrent interaction among actors.
- Individual level and aggregate level analysis both suffer from the same problem: they ignore the implications that arise due to patterns of individual interdependence located in time, place, and setting.
What are some of the methodological issues of the study of political information networks?
Absent direct measures on patterns of communication, neither the individual measures nor their associated aggregate versions directly address the specifics of communication and persuasion among the individuals who make up the aggregates.
Network studies are particularly useful in analyzing well defined populations - such as clergies, political elites, court, and legislatures.
an unfortunate limitation of egocentric networks is the failure to embed dyads within larger networks and in the context of all other dyads in that same network.
However, they aren’t straightforward when analyzing large populations - which is the primary object of study for scholars concerned with studies of mass behavior (egocentric network survey questions and snowball surveys can help address this; pg. 5-6)
Political communication networks are created at the intersection of individual choice (demand) and environmental supply (which is stochastic).
What are the substantive and theoretical insights generated by it?
People are more inclined to discuss politics with others who share similar political beliefs
Studies ALSO demonstrate that patterns of both agreement and disagreement can be profitably understood within complex processes of communication and persuasion
- This means that there is persistent heterogeneity of opinions in less-dense (larger) social networks people aren’t as afraid of disagreement as we initially thought
Political heterogeneity in the form of cross cutting cleavages can depress political participation BUT increased levels of tolerance (which might be good?)
Political communication networks are more important in less developed democracy, where parties are less institutionalize and politics is more volatile
Diversity of group discussion decreases the susceptibility of individuals to issue framing by elites
Network studies of political communication and persuasion provide a theoretical, analytical response to the human limitations of the citizen in democratic politics.
this is important because it to do with the cognitive limitations of individuals in being self-contained, fully informed, independent maximizers
particularly useful is social capital - which allows people to rely on one another for accurate information
political interdependence among citizens helps to explain why public opinion in the aggregate is more sophisticated than the opinions held by the average citizen - its more fully informed
solutions to collective action problems can be seen as occurring within networks of relationships among strategic actors who use the information they acquire through repeated interactions to facilitate group efforts
Schwartz, Shalom H., et al. 2014. “Basic Personal Values Underlie and Give Coherence to Political Values: A Cross-National Study in 15 Countries.” Political Behavior 36(4): 899-930.
Bumper Sticker:
Personal values explain political values!
Independent Variable:
Basic Personal Values
Dependent Variable:
Political Values
Research question: Do political attitudes and values of the general public form a coherent system? If so, what accounts for this structure and gives political values their coherence?
Political values = political expressions of more basic personal values
Basic personal values = security, achievement, benevolence, hedonism; organized on a circular continuum that reflects conflicting/compatible motivations
Data: data from 15 countries using 8 core political values and 10 basic personal values
Adults eligible to vote in Australia, Brazil, Chile, Germany, Greece, Finland, Israel, Italy, Poland, Slovakia, Spain, Turkey, Ukraine, United Kingdom, and UUS
Except in Australia, UK, Germany, & Turkey, respondents recruited by university students and completed self-report questionnaire individually
Methods:
use basic personal values to predict expected political values; different hypotheses for 12 non-communist and 3 post-communist countries
Data gathered in local language of each country
Portrait Values Questionnaire (PVQ) measure of 40 short verbal “portraits” of different people matched to respondents’ gender, each describing a person’s goals, aspirations, or wishes
3-6 items measure each value
For each portrait, respondents indicate how similar the person is to themselves from “not like me at all” –1 to “very much like me” –6
Multimethod-multitrait analyses of the 10 values measured with PVQ and with the Schwartz Value Survey
Findings:
correlation and regression analyses support almost all hypotheses
Basic values account for substantially more variance in political values than age, gender, education, and income
Multidimensional scaling analyses demonstrate graphically how circular motivational continuum of basic personal values structures relations among core political values
This study strengthens assumption that individual differences in basic personal values play a critical role in political thought (seems kinda obvious).
NEED TO INSERT FIGURES/PHOTOS!
Taber, Charles S., and Milton Lodge. 2006. “Motivated Skepticism in Evaluation of Political Beliefs.” American Journal of Political Science 50(3): 755-769.
Bumper Sticker:
People process information through prior bias and double down in the face of new information, resulting in attitude polarization about different issues
prior attitudes + bias for confirming evidence + skepticism of opposing evidence = attitude polarization
Research Question:
How do political beliefs evolve?
What explains political polarization in the face of factual information?
Summary of Theory/Argument:
The authors postulate what they call a theory of affect-driven motivated reasoning in trying to explain when and why citizens actively process biased information. This theory suggests that people will anchor their evaluation of new information in their own biases - being non-skeptical of information that confirms their biases and being “motivated- skepticals” when engaging in information that is counter to their biases - i.e. spending more time trying to discredit new information. The authors propose a process of “partisan processing” that results in attitude-polarization and which is conditional on the strength of ones prior attitudes and the level of one political sophistication. They test the mechanism as a series of hypothesis that assume the following form:
H1: there is a prior attitude effect whereby people who feel strongly about an issue - even when encouraged to be objective and leave their preferences aside - will evaluate supportive arguments as stronger and more compelling than arguments that oppose their prior beliefs
H2: there is a disconfirmation bias, such that people will spend more time and cognitive resources counter-arguing opposing arguments
H3: there is a confirmation bias, such that when free to choose what information they will expose themselves to, people will seek out confirming arguments over disconfirming ones
These combined will results in:
H4: attitude polarization, where attitudes will become MORE EXTREME, even when people have been exposed to a balanced set of pro and con arguments
Which is conditional upon:
H5: the level of attitude strength effect, such that citizens voicing the strongest policy attitudes will be the most prone to motivated skepticism
H6: and the degree of political sophistication effect, such that the politically knowledgeable will be more susceptible to motivated bias than will unsophisticates.
Data/Methods:
Two experimental studies explore how citizens evaluate arguments about affirmative action and gun control
The participants (Ps) were recruited from introductory political science courses at Stony Brook University
Study 1: N=126
Study 2: N=136
First Part: Confirmation Bias
The participants (Ps) were seated at computers and their political attitudes were assessed through the evaluation of a series of contemporary political issues aimed at activating their priors - this was done through random assignment into either condition 1 or condition 2 (see figure 1)
They rated the items on a series of scales to assess attitude strength (0-100) and attitude position (like-dislike; 9 item scale)
They then viewed information on an information board, where they could seek out hidden policy arguments by known source alone (see figure 2); the amount of time they spend engaging in each argument was recorded by the software.
They viewed eight arguments without a time limit, but could only view each argument ONCE
They then completed the same attitude battery from the beginning of the experiment before filing out demographic information and a political knowledge scale ( to assess sophistication)
Second Part: Disconfirmation Bias
administered the battery again, but with the conditions (issues) swapped.
then asked to rank the strength of 8 arguments (4 pro and 4 con)
then there was a post test battery AGAIN and a recognition memory test
they were also asked to list their thoughts regarding two pro and two con arguments they were presented with Arguments were taken from online sources and edited such that they were similar in complexity and length.
Findings:
strong evidence of a prior attitude effect (H1) such that attitudinally congruent arguments are evaluated as stronger than attitudinally incongruent arguments.
Participants counter-argued the contrary arguments and uncritically accept supporting arguments, evidence of a disconfirmation bias (H2) - this was supported by the participants spending MORE time on the policy arguments that they disagreed with
Also find a confirmation bias (H3)—the seeking out of confirmatory evidence—when Ps are free to self-select the source of the arguments they read - this was supported by the participants seeking out information in the matrix that they agreed with
Both the confirmation and disconfirmation biases lead to attitude polarization (H4) —the strengthening of t2 over t1 attitudes—especially among those with the strongest priors (H5) and highest levels of political sophistication (H6).
Week 4: Partisanship/Party Preference
Campbell, Angus, Philip E. Converse, Warren E. Miller, and Donald E. Stokes. 1960. The American Voter. Ch 6 & 7.
Bumper Sticker:
Party ID influences attitudes and behavior & is sticky!
- Mostly descriptive statistics. Lots of tables and figures.
Research Question:
What are the various impacts of individual party identification?
Data:
- Self-identified party identification from individuals on repeated cross sections of national population from 1952-1956 and strength and direction of partisan orientation
General Notes: TK
TK TK TK TK
Keele, Luke, and Jennifer Wolak. 2006. “Value conflict and volatility in party identification.” British Journal of Political Science 36(4): 671-690.
Bumper Sticker:
*Value conflict can explain why partisanship assumes both a steady AND changeable nature
Research Question:
The paradox of partisanship: Why is partisan identification stable for some people and not stable for others?
Summary/Theory/Argument:
Keele and Wolak seek to explain why some people are more prone to #partisan “instability” (or “volatility”) than others. To the authors, the reason for this has to do with the “hierarchy of values”. When people have obvious values that rank higher than others (humanitarianism, egalitarianism, equality) AND these #values align with political elites values, then partisan identity remains a steady tool with which to measure the political world against. HOWEVER, for some people, the values rank similarly and therefore cause conflicting #preferences that individuals struggle to resolve. Competing values will produce #volatility in partisan opinions specifically when individuals endorse values that cross the fault lines of partisan dialogue
Data/Methods:
Data: ANES data from 1992, 1994, and 1996
Model: Estimates several heteroskedastic regression models as well as ordered probit models The heteroskedastic regression models are used because they expect differences in the response variance of party identification survey items to reflect value-conflict
this is because citizens with ideologically inconsistent value structures will struggle to identify with one party or another
there should be unequal variance across observations (which is heteroskedastic)
this heteroskedasticity is modeled to see if those who experience value conflict reveal less predictable responses to party identification survey items than those who do
Independent Variable:
Value conflict
is measured using 4 core values in American Politics:
Egalitarianism, limited government, moral traditionalism, and humanitarianism
The measures for these values are derived from a set of ANES survey questions on each value
1992 and 1996 are the years they were taken from (1992 is missing humanitarianism)
Dependent Variable:
Partisan Instability
Two “manifestations”
predictability of survey response (those experience value conflict should have less predictable responses to partisan questions) to two survey questions:
- seven-point party identification scale and ideological self identification scale
change in party identification over time (this one is tested using the 1994 and 1996 panel data)
Findings:
1992 and 1996 elections reveal value-driven volatility in partisan identification
Instabilities in political views reflect either:
low information (for some)
trade-offs of the political world that cause conflict of values
Value conflict will disrupt partisan stability when an individuals value organization is non-ideological - i.e. it doesn’t quite fit the rhetoric or portrayal by the liberal vs. conservative, left-right spectrum. what makes it non-ideological is that you support values on BOTH sides
Those that have values the match political elites leads to stable partisanship
Those that have internalized value organization that doesn’t match elites leads to conflicts of values and partisan volatility.
Elites identify and interpret core values to justify their policy positions
Values and ideology are traditionally distinct concepts - but values can be distributed along an ideological spectrum
Hatemi, Peter K., et al. 2008. “Is there a ‘Party’ in Your Genes?” Political Research Quarterly 62(3): 584-600.
Bumper Sticker:
Genes don’t choose party, but they influence intensity!
Independent Variable:
Twins! MZ and DZ and familial party ID and intensity
Dependent Variable:
party identification and party intensity
Research question:
Do your genes determine political party identification?
Hypothesis:
Party identification (PID) is primarily the result of familial socialization and not other latent social or genetic influences.
Partisan intensity is influenced by genes as well as the environment.
Data:
- Data collected in mid- to late 1980s as part of Virginia 30,000 Health and Life-Style Survey for Twins (VA30K)
Methods:
Polychoric correlations by twin pair zygosity calculated for each of the traits.
Correlations between PID, partisan intensity, sociodemographic items, selected personality traits, and political attitudes calculated for males & females separately
Using structural equation modeling (SEM), variance of phenotypes separated into additive genetic (A), common environmental (C), & unique environmental influences (E)
Findings:
- NOPE – your genes don’t determine your political party
BUT!
- Genes play a pivotal role in the strength of your party ID
General notes:
Direction and Intensity of Political Affiliation
Family member political affiliations are highly correlated
Largely held as evidence of familial socialization
Researchers have failed to consider possibility of genetic component
Other social traits, behaviors, and attitudes are genetically influenced
Church attendance
Issue positions
Political ideology (isn’t this what we’re already talking about?)
We need to know both direction and strength of partisan attachments
Behavior Genetics and Biometric Theory
Developed in an attempt to understand why individuals in a population differ
Analyses explain variation around a population mean = info on individual differences in a population
Phenotype (specific trait value) = combo of genetics + environment
Monozygotic (MZ) twins often used in behavior genetic pop samples
If PID is influenced by genes, co-twin correlation of MZ twins should be higher than that of DZ twin pairs
Maximum likelihood (ML) structural equation modeling (SEM) most commonly used to analyze twin samples (Bayesian also used)
- Tests validity of theories
Model Assumptions and Addressing Critics of Biometric Designs
Classical Twin Design (CTD) assumes no differences in means (or prevalences) and variances of different zygosity groups
Also assumes magnitude and correlation of shared environmental influences are the same for MZ and DZ co-twin pairs (“equal environment assumption”)
Current polysci critiques outdated a priori assumptions that don’t test predictions
“The heuristic that genes influence behavior is unashamedly empirical, because that is the nature of science” (586).
Limitations exist:
- Twin samples are not random
Describing the Sample and the Measurement of Concepts
Data collected in mid- to late 1980s as part of Virginia 30,000 Health and Life-Style Survey for Twins (VA30K)
PID assessed by survey question: “Write in the number which best describes [your] political affiliation: (1) don’t know (2) always supports Republicans (3) usually supports Republicans (4) varies (5) usually supports Democrats (6) always supports Democrats (7) other (8) prefer not to answer.”
2 or 3 = Republican, 5 or 6 = Democrat, 4 = varies
Partisan intensity determined by usually and always
Sociodemographic variables: age, income, education, religion, occupation, marital status, church attendance
Political attitudes assessed using 28-item version of Wilson-Patterson attitudes inventory
Selection of covariates for partisan intensity include measures from Eysenck’s Personality Quotient (EPQ) with 3 main personality factors:
Psychoticism (versus impulse control)
Extraversion (versus introversion)
Neuroticism (versus instability)
Two additional subfactors – impulsivity and social conformity – also in sample and included in analysis
Definitions:
Monozygotic (MZ) twins = twins developed from a single fertilized ovum that are genetically identical
Dizygotic (DZ) twins = twins from 2 different fertilized ova by different sperm; on average only sharing 50% of segregating genes (like non-twin siblings)
Additive genetic (A) = combined influence of all genes
Common environment (C) = common or shared among family members, including familial and cultural socialization
Unique environment (E) = idiosyncratic (unique) personal experience and all environmental stimuli unique to the individual
A priori = knowledge independent from experience
Collapsed variable = combining several cases into single lines
Polychoric correlation = A technique for estimating the correlation between two hypothesized normally distributed continuous latent (indirectly measured) variables, from two observed ordinal variables
Discriminant function analyses = serve the same purpose as beta weights in linear regression and indicate the relative importance of the covariate in predicting the dependent variable
Week 5: Vote Choice - Socio-Contextual Mechanisms
Arzheimer, Kai. 2009. “Contextual Factors and the Extreme Right Vote in Western Europe, 1980-2002.” American Journal of Political Science 53(2): 259-275.
Huber, John, Georgia Kernell and Eduardo Leoni. 2003. “Institutional Context, Cognitive Resources, and Party Attachments Across Democracies.” Political Analysis 13(4): 365-386.
Bumper Sticker:
Party attachment follows from group identities when:
- The individual identifies as a member of the group
- Competing group identities are both in support of the same party.
- (also) Systems that help individuals evaluate party performance increase partisanship and this effect is most strongly associated with the least-educated individuals.
Independent Variable:
salience of groups, group cross pressures, & permissiveness of electoral system
measured through social heterogeneity, number of political parties, effective number of legislative parties
Retrospective clarity:
Effective number of legislative parties (as this increases, more difficult to assess responsibility for policy outcomes
Party cohesion (vote for candidate captures degree of interdependence between voting for a candidate and the candidate’s party)
Candidate control of ballot (captures candidates’ control of (1) access to a party’s label and (2) manipulation of ballot rankings in party list systems
Age of party system (logged and weighted by vote proportion age of up to the top 6 vote-receiving parties in CSES election)
Education:
- 1 (low) to 8 (high)
Dependent Variable:
Party attachment
Research Question:
Do some political systems encourage the formation of party attachments more than others? Are social structures or governmental institutions most important? Are the effects of political context the same for all individuals?
Hypothesis:
A country’s social and institutional context should have a systematic impact on party attachments.
The impact of social and institutional context does not operate the same on all types of individuals.
Data:
Countries with a 9 or 10 on Polity IV for at least the 2 years immediately prior to first module of that country’s CSES election survey (1996-201) = 25 countries (Thailand removed for corruption-plagued 2001 election)
Party attachment measured by answers to 2 CSES questions:
“Do you usually think of yourself as close to any particular political party?”
If yes, “What party is that” = party attachment; if no, = independents
Methods:
Two-step estimation procedure:
Probit model for each country estimating effects of individual-level attributes on likelihood of being a partisan
Linear regression to test socialization and institutional hypotheses with weighting matrix to weight coefficients from first-level regressions by their precision
Findings:
Voters form attachments when group identities are salient and complimentary.
Institutions that help voters evaluate parties increase partisanship.
These institutions retrospectively evaluate parties through party discipline and the number of parties in government.
These institutions have the greatest influence on voters with the least education.
Pattie, Charles, and Ron Johnston. 2000. “People Who Talk Together Vote Together: An Exploration of Contextual Effects in Great Britain.” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 90(1): 41-66.
Abstract:
Many students of British voting patterns have tested for the existence of contextual effects, which postulate that voters are influenced by events and people in their local milieux. One of those contextual effects is the neighborhood effect, whereby individuals are influenced by the nature of the politically relevant information circulating within their social networks, many of which are spatiallyconstrained to their local area. Although ecological analyses have identified patterns consistent with this hypothesis, there have been virtually no direct investigations of the effect, largely because of the absence of relevant data. Using information from a large, clustered survey of voters at the time of the 1992 general election, this paper uncovers clear evidence of such effects: people are much more likely to change their votes in a particular direction if those with whom they discuss political issues support that direction, especially if they are members of the respondent’s family and are the individuals with whom they discuss politics most.
Bumper Sticker:
Who we talk to is as important as who we are and who we talk to is very much influenced by where we live — we are what we are, and do what we do, because of where we are, and have been OR those who talk together tend to vote together.
Research Question:
Does the neighborhood effect have an impact on voter decisions?
Summary/Theory/Argument:
Most researchers have accepted that voters are influence by their immediate social and geographical environments as well as their own individual circumstances. However, the way in which such contextual factors operate is contested. Most explanations point to spatial variation in economic and political contexts and the driving force behind voter’s decisions. That is, “nonsocial” context on economic and political conditions at the local and national level compose the voting repertoire with which individuals draw on at the polls.
However, the authors speculate that the influence of immediate social networks (family, friends, colleagues) on individual opinions informs their voting behavior. Early research explored such possibilities, but scarcity of data left this “neighborhood effect” to be abandoned if favor of explanations that could be explored.
Hypothesis:
Main hypothesis: Each group would be influenced by the dominant nature of electorally relevant information in their social networks—those who changed the party that they supported should be in networks where support for their new party is strong, whereas those who remained loyal to a party should be in networks that give it strong support.
Data/Methods:
Explores contextual effects on voting behavior in Great Britain
Uses data collected in the British Election Study (BES) from the 1992 British General Election, which lends itself to the data requirement of networks of people living in the same locality.
The data uses a cluster rather than a random sample: 210 “points” (which are polling districts made up of 1,000-2,000 voters).
Used a stratified random design with a random sample of respondents selected from the electoral roll for the district
Produces 2,526 individuals with an average sample size of around 16 per cluster, with a peaked distribution between 16 and 19
Authors chose to focus on why some respondents, from their own recollection, changed their vote between 1987 and 1992 while others did not
By aggregating the reported 1987 votes of each BES respondent by polling district, the authors were able to estimate the vote share there for each of the three main political parties that fought in all British constituencies in both 1987 and 1992: Conservative, Labour, and Liberal Democrat (Alliance in 1987).
First analysis:
Contrasts those who switched their vote to a particular party in 1992 (coded 1) against those who didn’t (coded 0)
Gives 3 dependent variables:
- 1. switch to conservative 2) switch to labor 3) switch to Liberal
Employs a Logistic Regression (because the DVs are binary)
Then does the same thing but looks at those who defected (voted for each party in 1987) So those who voted for a particular party in 1987 and again in 1992 (the loyalists) against those that voted for another party/ didn’t vote at all in 1992 (the defectors)
Second analysis:
looks at the impact of conversations with the individuals respondents named as the first (primary) discussant of politics and analyzing how that affected transitions to each party
Measures those who who didn’t vote for the same party in 1992 as they did in 1987 against those who did
Also looks at those who defected versus those who didn’t
Third analysis:
Assesses the degree to which cross cutting relationships impact vote choice by bringing in two additional discussants that the respondents listed
The more discussants who support a particular party, the greater the expected probability that an individual will switch to that party, and the less the probability that he or she will defect from it.
Fourth analysis:
It’s possible that discussants don’t live in the same neighborhood (i.e. context) as the respondent. Therefore, there a chance that political context and conversations on voting linked, or could they be separate?
hypothesize that the more support a party has in a locality (the independent variables employed in the regressions reported in Tables 3 and 4), the greater the probability that individuals there will encounter, talk to, and be converted by that party’s partisans
tested by dividing the respondents according to how many discussants they report having a particular partisanship, which can vary from 0 to 3.
Findings:
Social networks are indeed important influences on voting decisions
Families who talk together, vote together! (kinda) - voters were more likely to vote/not vote for a party based on conversations they had with their families
More accurately: those who talked together tended to vote together.
Conversations with friends are also important
First analysis:
the more their local area was dominated by supporters of a particular party, the greater the probability that individuals switched their support to that party between 1987 and 1992—if they had not voted for it at the first of those two election
local context did not influence voters’ decisions to abandon a party they have previously supported, but that the choice of which party to switch their support to was influenced by local conditions—which is the hypothesized mechanism that underlies the neighborhood effect.
Second analysis:
Those who did not voter conservative in 1987 were more likely to vote conservative in 1992 if their primary discussant was conservative
- talking to Labour or Liberal party discussants made not conservative voters less likely to vote conservative (duh)
Same results hold for other parties - voters were more likely to vote for a particular party if the primary discussant was a member of that party
Frequency of conversation about politics appeared to have no influence
those people who voted for a party in 1987 were less likely to vote for another party in 1992 if their primary discussant had been a supporter of the same parter when compared to their discussant being from another party or having no discussant at all
Third analysis:
- More likely to support and less likely to defect if the discussants were from the same party
Fourth Analysis:
If a respondent had more discussants from a particular party, then there was also an associated increase in the number of votes for that party in the respondents district
This shows that there is a link between spatial and communicative contexts, supporting the neighboring effects.
It is not logical to ignore social networks, and conversations within them, as a possible influence on the voting decision of individuals
Non-Findings:
Can’t distinguish if the influential conversations are locally based
They know that the conversations matter, but they have no information on the relative locations of the individuals involved in those conversations (how immediate are they?).
Also don’t know what the content of the conversations were
NEED TO ADD WESTHOLM
Week 6: Vote Choice - Economic Motivations
Bratten, Michael, and Robert Mattes. 2001. “Support for Democracy in Africa: Intrinsic or Instrumental?” British Journal of Political Science 31(3): 447-474.
Bumper Sticker:
African democracy persists b/c of economic AND political change.
Independent Variable:
economic, political, and general performance factors on democratic regime
Dependent Variable:
attitudes about democracy
Research Question:
Why do Africans support democracy?
Hypothesis:
Explanatory factors: why variation in support for/satisfaction with democracy?
Social characteristics of population such as literacy, income and gender
Economic goods: popular perceptions of national economic conditions, personal quality of life, and access to materials and services shape feelings about democracy
Political goods: Is the delivery of civil rights and political equality enough?
General performance factors: citizens’ overall assessment of governmental performance for 3 reasons:
Data:
3 separate surveys on political attitudes in Ghana, Zambia, and South Africa
Zambia: 1,182 respondents following “dubious” 1996 election
South Africa: 3,500 stratified by race, province, community size in 1997 following free & fair elections
Ghana: 2,005 respondents in 1999 following free & fair 1996 elections
- All 3 surveys included questions on citizen understanding of the meaning of democracy, support for, and satisfaction with democracy in theory and n practice
Methods:
Multiple regression in OLS
Findings:
Popular support for democracy in African countries similar to other Third Wave countries
Lower levels of mass satisfaction w/regime performance in African countries
General public in African countries thinks instrumentally: support for democracy hinges critically upon popular approval of government achievements
Outside of South Africa, many Africans value political goods
Additional findings:
Africans [here] more likely to associate democracy w/individual liberties than w/communal solidarity, especially if they live in urban areas.
Popular conceptions of democracy have both procedural and substantive dimensions (though the former is more common than the latter).
Citizens rank procedural and substantive attributes in different order across countries.
Rankings differ even within the category of political goods
Benton, A. L. (2005). “Dissatisfied Democrats or retrospective voters?”, 38(4), 417–442.
Abstract:
This article examines recent trends in #Latin-American #voting-behavior and casts them in terms of sincere (economic) and strategic (electoral) concerns. It argues that thanks to years of economic adversity, Latin Americans have developed long, sophisticated #economic-memories . Although this has resulted in rising frustration with democratic government, according to recent opinion polls, it has not always led voters to #punish all parties responsible for hardship at election time. A panel study of the region’s presidential systems demonstrates that citizens punish incumbents by voting for established #nonincumbents when electoral laws reduce opportunities available to small parties in the systems, even if #nonincumbents have also been blamed for hard economic times. More #permissive-electoral-systems , in contrast, encourage citizens to reject all parties responsible for economic decline. The analysis demonstrates how economic and electoral concerns interact to affect voting behavior, #political-accountability , and #public-opinion in Latin America.
Bumper Sticker:
Economic Evaluations Voter Laws Voter Behavior
Research Question:
If most Latin Americans have faced economic hardship during successive governments, why do they reject both the incumbent and non-incumbent parties in some systems and only the incumbent party in others?
Summary/Theory/Argument:
Many Latin American economies have experienced some form poor performance that has resulted in different forms of electoral punishment. Barton, drawing on previous literature regarding economic theories of voter behavior, devises a theory that enables her to assess the institutional features that interact with economic performance to determine who voters choose to punish in subsequent elections. In highly permissible systems, where there are more parties to choose from, voters memories of economic performance can interact with electoral strategies to allow the punishment of multiple parties (as has been the case in multiple countries). However, more restrictive systems, which limit the number of viable parties, forces voters to focus their punishing efforts on the incumbent alone, as they require an alternative option of some form and therefore increases support for the form incumbent.
Data/Methods:
panel data from 13 Latin American Countries
required (a) to be a presidential system and have had (b) more than one party win the presidency, so that current and former incumbents compete; (c) to have elections deemed free of fraud by international observers, so that their results reflect voters’ reactions to party performance; and (d) to have an economic crisis and/or economic reform during democratic rule.
in these countries, 64 elections were held, with 39 instances in which current and former incumbents competed for power
Independent Variable:
economic performance as measured by the percentage change in GDP per capita during each parties last 2 years in office.
Dependent Variable:
Change in support for incumbents - measured as the difference between votes received by an incumbent party in presidential elections while in office and votes received in the previous election when the party won.
Change in support for non-incumbents out of power - measured as change in support received in elections after leaving office and support when the party originally came into power.
Model:
- Uses OLS with #panel-corrected standard errors #PCSEs , which were selected because of the limited number of countries and small (often unbalanced) number of observations in each panel.
Hypothesis:
H1: When incumbent parties are blamed for poor economic performance, they will lose support, regardless of the electoral system used to elect them.
H2: Nonincumbent parties previously in power will derive greater electoral benefits in restrictive, compared with permissive, electoral contexts when incumbent parties are blamed for economic decline, all else being equal.
H3: Former incumbents blamed for economic decline will continue to receive lower levels of support in permissive, as opposed to restrictive, electoral contexts, all else being equal.
H4: Current incumbents will gain support in permissive, as opposed to restrictive, electoral contexts when former incumbents are blamed for economic decline, all else being equal.
Findings:
Hypothesis | Support | Details |
---|---|---|
H1 | Yes | incumbent parties’ support decreases with economic downturns, without regard to institutional change (p.430) |
H2 | Yes | when electoral laws construct institutional barriers to small parties (restrictive), groups once holding the presidency will suffer losses in support when incumbents manage economic growth; as GDP declines, parties previously in power begin to experience a surge of supprot (p.431) |
H3 | Yes | accounting for the presence of Honduras, there was no relationship between poor economic performance and punishment of former incumbents in restrictive systems; there was a relationship between poor economic performance and the punishment of incumbents in permissive systems (pg.436) |
H4 | Yes | nonincumbents’ performance has implications for incumbents’ support. As predicted, incumbents gain about 10% of the national votes when nonincumbents are responsible for neoliberal economic reform in all electoral settings |
Other Findings:
Restrictive institutions reduce the incentive for voters to waste support on parties unlikely to win.
Rather than helping nonincumbents weather the electoral effect of incumbents’ economic growth, runoffs cause nonincumbents to suffer additional electoral losses.
Lewis-Beck, Michael S., and Mary Stegmaier. 2009. “Economic Models of Voting.” OHPB. Ch. 27: 518-537.
Bumper Sticker:
The state of the economy can help predict voter decisions.
Purpose:
This is a literature review on micro-level, survey research studies of economic voting in the U.S., Britain, France, and Globally.
Overview:
Questions regarding the precise nature of economic voting led to four general “types”.
- Retrospective Voting
- Originating with V.O. Key (1966), this type of voting occurs when voters review the performance of the incumbent government.
- Prospective Voting
- Originating with Downs (1957), this type of voting occurs when voters look to the future and vote according to the governments potential economic performance.
- Pocketbook Voting (personal finances)
- This theory of voting suggests that when personal or household financial conditions have deteriorated, voters will punish the incumbent.
- Sociotropic Voting (national economy rather than personal finances).
- This theory of voting suggests that voters are more likely to be considering the national economic situation when casting their vote.
Of these types, the retrospective sociotropic and prospective sociotropic appear to be the most relevant across empirical evaluations. That is, people tend to vote based of their perceptions of national economic performance, both in the past (retrospective sociotropic) and the future (prospective sociotropic). The type of voting that is cued depends on whether or not an incumbent is running, and therefore a reliable place to point blame. Essentially, the reward-punishment hypothesis holds up across settings, with slight variation according to group membership (party id, gender, etc.), institutional context (voting system, prime-minister v. president, number of parties) and economic context (personal, neighborhood, national).
Findings:
United States:
- ANES is good source for election studies
- Most theories of economic voting focus on the U.S.
- Pocketbook voting is weak in presidential elections -- sociotropic is strong
- Strength of economic voting can cary based on context -- such is the case when considering the attribution of responsibility (e.g. the attribution of blame to particular party/candidate/branch of government)
- in the U.S. the presidency is an important institutional context for which to blame punish electorally
- While other types of factors matter and interact them, sociotropic economic effects (both retrospective and prospective) themselves cannot be understated when assessing the general behavior of the voter population.
Britain:
- BES is a good source for election studies
- British voters show the same trends of reward and punishment regarding economic voting
- There may be important regional contexts
- Johnston 1997 finds that when voter’s perceptions of their neighborhoods are that they are worse off, they will punish the incumbent
- Retrospective and Prospective are both important
- Perceptual shifts in economic conditions are almost as great as realigning with a different party (Clarke et al. 2004)
France:
- Eurobarometer and FNES are good sources for election studies
- A general finding—significant retrospective sociotropic effects, but no retrospective pocketbook effects
- It is largely sociotropic and more or less equally retrospective or prospective, depending in part on the institutional context.
- The French voter is sophisticated, knowing whom and how much to blame.
- When government is unified, the president is the lightning rod for economic discontent. However, under cohabitation, the burden shifts to the prime minister.
- Smaller parties are blamed less than large parties, legislative candidates are blamed less than presidential candidates, and presidential candidates who are prime minister are blamed more than presidential candidates who are not prime minister.
Cross-National Studies:
- Similar trends have been found in cross-national studies
- Lewis‐Beck and Mitchell (1990), on the five major western European countries; Chappell and Veiga (2000), on thirteen western European nations; Pacek (1994) and Tucker (2001) on central European samples; Remmer (1991) on twelve Latin American countries; Pacek and Radcli (1995) on eight low‐income nations; Wilkin, Haller, and Norporth (1997) on a worldwide sample of countries.
- Important Takeaways:
Responsibility Hypothesis seems to hold - that when responsibility is hard to pin down, voters are less likely to punish incumbents - this is an important contextual factors
Such is the case in more countries with more “coalitional complexity” -- when more parties make up the incumbent government, is it difficult to assign blame
Presidential Systems and systems with more restrictive electoral laws tend to strengthen the economic vote
In the context of globalization, there is a significant decrease in economic voting in the face of open trade, as electorates can’t assign blame to the government alone
Week 7: Societal Cleavages
Inglehart, Ronald, and Pippa Norris. 2003. Rising Tide: Gender Equality and Cultural Change around the World. Cambridge University Press. Ch. 1&2.
Bumper Sticker:
Modernization theory applies to positive gender equality attitudes!
IV:
societal modernization
DV:
gender equality attitudes
Research question:
How has modernization changed attitudes towards gender equality? How much does culture matter for gender equality compared to levels of societal development and legal-institutional structures?
Hypotheses:
Societal modernization brings changed cultural attitudes toward gender equality through:
a transition from traditional to secular-rational values, and
a transition from survival to self-expression values.
These shifts are coherent and predictable, and can be shown through:
Cross-national comparisons
Sectoral comparisons (most secure vs. less secure sectors of the public)
Gender comparisons
Generational comparisons
Religious legacies – controlling for society’s level of GNP per capita & workforce structure, Islamic societies will be less supportive of gender equality (19)
Data:
Evidence of changing attitudes towards gender equality in over 70 countries using the World Values and European Values surveys from 1981-2001
Types of societies:
Human Development Index 100-point scale of societal modernization using adult literacy and education, life expectancy, and real per capita GDP
Postindustrial societies = 28 states w/HDI over .9 and mean per capita GDP of $29,585
Industrial societies = 58 states w/HDI .74-.899 and GDP of at least $6,314
Agrarian societies = 97 states w/HDI <.739 and GDP of $1,098
Types of states:
Gastil index, 7-point scale used by Freedom House, as a standard measure of political rights and civil liberties (higher score = higher levels of democracy)
Length of democratic stability from Freedom House ratings, 1972-2000
Older democracies = 39 states w/> 20 yrs as dem & 5.5-7.0 FH rating
Newer democracies = 43 states w/< 20 yrs as a dem & 5.5-7.0 FH rating
Semi-democracies = 47 states w/< 20 yrs as a dem & 3.5-5.5 FH rating
Non-democracies = 62 states w/FH rating of 1.0-3.0
Analysis of cultural attitudes using World Values Survey (WVS) pooled survey with all waves; combined with Eurobarometer Survey and Political Action Study to fill in gaps
Methods:
“Convergence model” using Przeworski & Teune’s “most different system” design
- Seeks to maximize contrasts among societies to distinguish systematic clusters of characteristics associated with different dimensions of gender equality
Findings:
Cultural traditions are enduring in shaping men’s and women’s worldviews (but not enough on their own)
Slow shifts are taking place to move from traditional towards more egalitarian sex roles
Where there are more egalitarian attitudes, these are systematically related to the actual conditions of women’s and men’s lives
Questions:
- Inglehart & Norris describe social modernization and the gender equality attitudes that accompany it as “probabilistic, not deterministic” (11). But if these slow attitudinal changes are happening across the majority of the population, how do we account for democratic backsliding and the rise of violence against minorities in postindustrial countries following exogenous shocks/social strains? (think terrorist attacks, economic shocks like the 2008 recession, mass migration/immigration from Syria, etc.). Do we think that these represent latent variables that were always present? Are they blips along a long-term progressive path? Or do they represent something more insidious?
General Notes:
This book sets out to understand how modernization has changed cultural attitudes toward gender equality and to analyze the political consequences of this process
Core arguments: people’s lives have been changed in 2-stage modernization process:
Shift from agrarian to industrialized societies
Move from industrial to postindustrial societies
Chapter 1: Introduction – Explaining the Rising Tide of Gender Equality
Women’s progress worldwide uneven – lagging in government representation
UN encouraged states to recognize women’s rights through Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Discrimination against Women (CEDAW) 1979
- “...the role of the state is now widely understood to be central in actively consolidating and reinforcing gender equality” (7).
Cultural barriers: perceptions of appropriate division of roles in home and family, paid employment, and political spere shaped by predominant culture – the social norms, beliefs, and values in society
Thes norms, beliefs and values rest on levels of societal modernization and religious traditions
Gender = the socially constructed roles and learned behavior of women and men associated with the biological characteristics of females and males
Cultural change not sufficient itself for gender equality but is a necessary condition for gender equality
Modernization brings systematic, predictable changes in gender roles in 2 phases:
Industrialization → women into paid workforce → reduced fertility rates, increased literacy and greater educational opportunities → greater female participation in representative government (but still less power than men)
Postindustrialization → women rise in management and professions → women gain political influence in elected & appointed bodies (over half of women worldwide haven’t entered this phase yet)
- Changes probabilistic, not deterministic (11)
Chapter 2: From Traditional Roles toward Gender Equality
Four major predictions – expect to find systematic differences in cultural indicators of gender equality:
between societies based on their level of economic development
within societies based on generational cohorts
between women and men, and
within societies based on structural and cultural factors such as education and class
This chapter analyzes indirect attitudinal evidence
This study develops a Gender Equality Scale by combining 5 items from the pooled 1995-2001 World Values Surveys/European Values Surveys
MENPOL Q118: “On the whole, men make better political leaders than women do.” (Agree coded low) (1990-2001 WVS/EVS)
MENJOBS Q78: “When jobs are scarce, men should have more right to a job than women.” (Agree coded low) (1990-2001 WVS/EVS)
BOYEDUC Q119: “A university education is more important for a boy than a girl.” (Agree coded low) (1990-2001 WVS/EVS)
NEEDKID Q110: “Do you think that a woman has to have children in order to be fulfilled or is this not necessary?” (Agree coded low) (1981-2001 WVS/EVS)
SGLMUM Q112: “If a woman wants to have a child as a single parent but she doesn’t want to have a stable relationship with a man, do you approve or disapprove?” (1981-2001 WVS/EVS)
- Principal component factor analysis revealed that all 5 items tap a single dimension (see Table 2.1) w/Cronbach’s Alpha of 0.54*
Gender Equality Scale summed across items & standardized to 100 points
- Mean score for postindustrial societies = 80%; 68% for industrial; 60% for agrarian
Figure 2.2: plot of logged GDP per cap vs. Gender Equality Scale; R2 = 0.54
Iverson, Torben, and Frances Rosenbluth. 2006. “The Political Economy of Gender: Explaining Cross-National Variation in the Gender Division of Labor and the Gender Voting Gap.” American Journal of Political Science 50(1): 1-19.
Bumper Sticker:
“Bargaining power in the home explains gender gap for labor and voting”
Research Question:
What explains cross-national variation in the gender division of labor and the gender voting gap?
Summary/Argument:
The traditional “efficiency model” proposed by economists in explaining gender division of labor as the the outcome of a coordination game, whereby specialization in household versus market skills are reinforced by childhood socialization intended to maximize offsprings chances of success later in life, is itself incapable of explaining the stark differences in female labor force participation across economies of comparable levels of development.
Builds on economic bargaining models to show that the division of labor puzzle can only be understood by treating marriage as a incomplete contract that is potentially subject to termination. When such is the case, both men and women have an incentive to cultivate their outside options by entering into paid work, and the distribution of unpaid work is determined by bargaining powers dependent upon the political-economic factors outside the family.
What is important is that divorce is an option that varies across contexts. In places where divorce is a more viable, then outside options become important for long-term welfare. Meaning that both sexes will prefer social and economic policies that maximize these options, even if it reduces household income or other measures of aggregate welfare.
Men are disincentivized to support their wives working because 1.) it increases her agency/options to exit the marriage and 2.) increases the amount of work he has to do in the home. Additionally, women in specific skills economies typically bear a bigger penalty for career interruptions such as for child rearing, they face more limited work opportunities and may invest less in their market-relevant education as a result. This, in turn, weakens their bargaining power at home, and they get stuck sweeping floors more of the time than their counterparts in economies that specialize in general skills. This occurs unless the government steps in and adopts policies to counter the disadvantages of women in specific skills countries. This is where the gender gap in preferences enters the story.
Lijphart, Arend. 1979. “Religious vs. Linguistic vs. Class Voting: The ‘Crucial Experiment’ of Comparing Belgium, Canada, South Africa and Switzerland.” American Political Science Review 73(2): 442-458.
Bumper Sticker:
Religion and Language Highly Influence Voting Preferences!
IV:
Religiosity, class, and language
DV:
Party choice/voting behavior
Research question:
How do language and religion influence voter preferences?
Data:
- Survey data from 4 separate countries around roughly similar time periods
Methods:
Multivariate analysis comparing 4 countries
- AID technique – automatic interaction detector (tree analysis)
Findings:
- In “decisive trial of strength,” religion is the most influential factor, followed closely by language, with class a distant third.
Questions:
Lijphart’s methods may have been advanced by 1979 standards, but if you were to design a modern study that tested the same variables, how would you design it?
Why is there no mention of apartheid and its effect on South African voter preferences? Does this amount to omitted variable bias that can be corrected in the model or does the South African case present so many problems as to favor removing it from the study?
General Notes:
2 especially important social and demographic bases of voting behavior on party choice:
Social class
Religion
What about language?
Linguistic cleavages fairly uncommon in Western democracies
3 Western countries that are linguistically divided: Belgium, Canada, & Switzerland
- South Africa an interesting 4th case due to its white electorate and persistence of competitive free elections since 1945, high rank on socioeconomic indicators of industrialization, and Christian cultural origins
Alternative Comparative Strategies: The value of a “crucial experiment”
Alford’s index of class voting: divide voters into manual and non-manual workers and parties into left and right
Religious & language dimensions: dichotomous division of Protestants and Catholics, frequent churchgoers (at least twice/mo.) and those attending infrequently or never, and people speaking the majority language vs. speaking the minority language
Table 1: classification of political parties in 4 systems
Table 2: indices of class, religious, and linguistic voting in the 4 countries; top half unadjusted (uncontrolled) indices; adjusted lower half represent “pure” voting index of a particular independent variable when the other independent variables are controlled
- “Alford’s indices of voting, which are differences in proportions, can also be interpreted as the regression coefficients for the regression of party choice on the independent variables if these dichotomized variables are given the numerical values of 0 and 1. This important characteristic of the index makes it possible to use multiple regression analysis to compute controlled indices of voting” (445).
Class doesn’t have much effect (except +21 for Switzerland)
Table 3: percentages of support for the “religious” parties among respondents classified by 4 frequencies of curch attendance and church affiliation
- nonpracticing Catholics bheave very much like Protestants
Table 4: percentages of support for th “religious” parties cross-tabulated according to religion and language
- Religion and language are mutually reinforcing determinants of party choice in Belgiium, Canada, and Switzerland
Tree Analyses of Patterns of Party Choice – presented in Figures 1-4
Lyons, J., Utych, S.M. 2023. “You’re Not From Here!: The Consequences of Urban and Rural Identities.” Political Behavior 45: 75–101.
Bumper Sticker:
“Rural and Urban identities exist and influence preferences in predictable ways”
Research Question:
To what extent do urban and rural identities exist above and beyond other factors like party and race?
Are these identities consequential for the ways in which people evaluate the political and non-political world?
Abstract:
As the American political landscape becomes increasingly divided along urban–rural lines, it raises the prospect of deepening social identities that are tied to one’s community-type. As community-type becomes an important social identity, it can lead to favoritism of one’s community in-group, or denigration of one’s community out-group. We explore the extent to which urban and rural identities exist above and beyond other factors like party and race, and whether they are consequential for the ways in which people evaluate the political and non-political world. Using national survey data, we demonstrate that people in both urban and rural locations hold beliefs that are consistent with a community-type social identity that is independent of other factors which are correlated with the urban–rural divide. We use two different experiments to assess the consequences of this identity, finding that there are distinct effects in the political arena when allocating government resources, and in the non-political world when judging hypothetical job applications. These effects are generally smaller in magnitude than other factors, such as partisanship, but suggest that community-type identities are important in politics.
Summary/Theory/Argument:
Lyons and Utych set out to assess what appears to be a growing divide between rural and urban party affiliation and voting patterns.They explore the extent to which people use information about rural and urban community types to form impressions about American politics, as well as how people use this information to make decisions about political and non-political matters. If people are using urban and rural identities in similar ways to partisanship, and partisanship uses group identity as a way of perceiving the world, then there is a chance that people may be using geographic information such as urban and rural community type to evaluate the political and interpersonal landscape around them.
They focus on discriminatory behaviors. If urban and rural community types are taking on the qualities of social identities, then the in-group and out-group processing of information along lines of community type should be salient. That is, those from urban (rural) locations should confer a preference to urban (rural) locations/people, and a penalty to rural (urban) locations/people when making decisions that allocate resources, benefits, or opportunities.
Data/Methods:
Uses three different studies
First Study:
First, uses National Survey Data to show that people perceive values differences between people who live in rural and urban places -- appear to be driven by more than just party or race
do people who live in rural (urban) areas think that people who live in urban (rural) places are different than them, and do they think that they are getting an unfair shake from government relative to those who live in other community types?
Pew Research Center’s American Trends Panel (Wave 32)
Ordered logit
IV:
whether the respondents live in urban or rural setting
DV:
perceptions of others values
- used by creating a dichotomous variable from three survey questions (p.80)
perceptions of government distribution of resources across community types
- also created a dichotomous variable from survey questions (p.84-85)
Second Study:
Second, uses a conjoint experiment to explore where urban or rural identities are consequential for how people distribute resources in a hypothetical political scenario
conducted on Amazon’s Mechanical Turk (MTurk) in July 2019.7 We recruited 572 respondents to participate in the study, who were paid $1.25 to participate in a study that took less than 10 min, on average.
over representative of young, liberal, white, educated, male
First, participants were provided a sample pairing of two cities, to familiarize themselves with the task. Participants were told they were in charge of allocating $50,000 in highway funding between two cities. These cities were randomly assigned to vary on three dimensions—location (urban, suburban, or rural), mayor partisanship (Republican, Democrat, or non-partisan), year of last investment (2006, 2012, or 2018), percentage African-American (5%, 20%, or 65%) and average household income ($30,000, $60,000, or $90,000). Each individual completed the practice trial, and then 15 test trials.
key variation is based on the “location” variation, allowing us to compare how individuals allocate funding between urban, suburban, and rural areas.
One observation for each trial includes city characteristics for City A, while the second observation includes city characteristics for City B.
D.V.
- the allocation decision between City A or City B, which takes a value of 1 if the respondent allocates funding to that city, and 0 if they allocate funding for the other city.
Findings:
Find that rural identities influence opinions and that partisans react to urban and rural information in expected ways
Find that Democrats are more likely prefer urban areas to suburban areas, but not difference in the allocation of resources between Urban and Rural Republicans, however, are more likely to allocate to rural areas
No location based preferences for rural respondents
Third Study:
Third, uses a resume experience to test discrimination in a non-political setting, finding that people evaluate hypothetical job applicants more favorably when they are from the same community types
recruited 1467 respondents via MTurk who live in urban or rural areas13 to participate in the study, who were paid $0.50 to participate in a study that took roughly 2.5 min to complete, on average.
Participants shown a hypothetical resume and then asked to rate the applicant on a series of evaluative criteria/ traits
participants had preference for co-location
Expectations:
urban and rural identities are formative for the way in which people view themselves and others, and it is in ways that go above and beyond race, partisanship, and other demographic or socioeconomic factors
Democrats should discriminate in a fashion that confers favor to urban locations or people, while Republicans should show a preference for rural locations or people.
Findings:
Both urban and rural locations hold beliefs that are consistent with a community-type social identity that is independent of other factors
Each identity has a distinct impact on the political arenas when is comes to allocating government resources
Also has an impact in the non-political world when judging job applications
Effects are smaller than other factors, such as partisanship
Less educated community residents are more likely to perceive values difference
In rural places, so are younger people, males, whites, liberals, and non-religious service attenders
results are particularly related to rural areas
For government resources
- People who are older, more educated, Republicans and very conservative are the most likely to believe that urban area get more than their fair share of resources. By far the largest effect is from ideology (0.57 change in predicted probability across the full range), with partisanship (0.47 change in predicted probability) and age (0.22 change in predicted probability) also resulting in meaningful changes in predicted probabilities.
urban residents appear to have a well-defined out group, but it isn’t rural areas, it is the suburbs
Posner, Daniel N. 2004. “The Political Salience of Cultural Difference: Why Chewas and Tumbukas Are Allies in Zambia and Adversaries in Malawi.” American Political Science Review 98(4): 529-545.
Bumper Sticker:
When it comes to groups, relative size matters
Research Question:
Why do some cultural differences matter for politics and others not?
IV:
Political salience of cultural difference
DV:
Relative group size for coalition-building= cultural demography theory
Unit of Analysis:
cultural dyad= relationship between the two groups on either side of the border, not the individual ethnic group
Data/Methods:
Collect data on the border in July and August 2001: questionnaire in 4 villages/each pair facing each other across the border.
• Homogeneity of populations (equidistant from Ngoni population that could have “contaminated” the sample villages)
• Similarity, control naturally for geo and eco factors by choosing pairs in the same vicinitude
• Exposed to similar national political affairs and markets (proxied by paved routes)
• 42 interviews in each Zambia villages/48 in each Malawi villages= 180 total obs.
• Focus groups as supplement
Findings:
• Each group understand objective differences (Malawians more negative about the other)
• Difference in how they would allow the other group to integrate their lives politically or in the family sphere= Malawi side prefers separation at more than 50% on average where it is 20% on the other side (series of categorical mean tested differences)
• Biggest predictor is the physical location of the village NOT objective cultural difference.
• The physical location makes a political salience of intergroup difference=how much they attach meaning to their differences (537)= Meaning-making (Wedeen)
Week 9: Ethnicity/Tolerance
Hopkins, Daniel J. 2010. “Politicized Places: Explaining Where and When Immigrants Provoke Local Opposition.” American Political Science Review 104(1): 40-60.
Bumper Sticker:
Changing demographics X issue salience = anti-immigration attitudes
Research Question:
Under what conditions do people’s local experiences influence their political attitudes?
IV:
change in demographics and immigration salience/coverage
DV:
immigration attitudes and anti-immigration ordinances
Hypothesis:
- People living in changing communities will have more negative attitudes on immigration provided that immigration is nationally salient, and thus that frames related to immigration are available to politicize people’s day-to-day experiences.
Data:
11 surveys about politics & public affairs that included the same question about levels of immigration; included county-level geocodes
GSS: 1994, 1996, 2000
NES: 1992, 1994, 1996, 1998, 2000, 2004
SCCBS: 2006
KN: 2009
Salience of immigration measure: index of monthly mentions of immigration by 2 network news programs (ABC & CBS news) and country’s most widely circulated newspaper (USA Today) using Vanderbilt Television News Archive and LexisNexis database
Methods:
Descriptive statistics, correlation, and predicted probabilities
Index measure: Sum of immigration stories that month divided by avg number of immigration-related stories per month over time period Jan. 1992-Feb. 2009
- Salience measure t = (# of ABC stories)/1.8 + (# of CBS stories)/2.0 + (# of USA Today stories)/38.1
Support for immigration measured in pooled dataset of 15,851 respondents in 1,908 different counties
- County-level change remarkably stable over time
Immigration salience matches each respondent to avg level of immigration coverage in 6 months prior to respondent’s interview; missing data imputed
Findings:
- Strong negative interaction between salience and residence in a changing county
Questions:
Table 4 shows the percentage of demographic voters in a county as a control, but the paper doesn’t discuss it much. Would the findings hold up if repeated now, and would they change significantly given variation in a blue or red county?
With the recent actions of Republican governors exporting immigrants to blue counties with low-immigrant populations, would we see the kind of anti-immigrant sentiment that this paper predicts? Why or why not?
General Notes:
According to theories of racial threat, rising numbers of immigrants will threaten long-time residents’ political power and economic status
- This generates political hostility in heavily immigrant areas
This article develops the politicized places hypothesis to explain how and when local demographics influence attitude and local politics
3 factors minimize threat immigrants pose to long-time residents:
Immigrants are often unable to vote
Immigrants tend to work in segmented labor markets
Immigrants tent to live in segregated communities
Politicized places hypothesis (PPH): when communities are undergoing sudden demographic changes at the same time that salient national rhetoric politicizes immigration, immigrants can quickly become the targets of local political hostility
Realistic group threat: the presence of an outgroup in sufficient numbers will generate competition for scarce resources and thus local hostility
Local; threat might be acute in places of relative/increasing resource deprivation or rising outgroup political power
These assumptions don’t hold for immigrants – leads to politicized places hypothesis
Politicizted places hypothesis assertions:
Resolves issue of local inattention to demographics by arguing that while levels of ethnic heterogeneity might escape notice, changes are less likely to do so
Demographic changes might not be seen as having political ramifications unless frames are available that make those ramifications clear
Past work presents compelling evidence that framing effects can shape extent to which Americans’ attitudes toward public policies are racialized
PPH specifies conditions of everyday life that make symbols or rhetoric more or less influential
Central claim of PPH: At times when rhetoric related to immigrants is highly salient nationally, those witnessing influxes of immigrants locally will find it easier to draw political conclusions from their experiences.
- The driver is changes in demographics in affected places
Kalyvas, Stathis. 1999. “Wanton and Senseless? The Logic of Massacres in Algeria.” Rationality and Society 11(3): 243-285.
Bumper Sticker:
“Mass violence against civilians is not irrational”
Purpose:
This paper seeks to address a gap in the literature on revolutions and rebellions - which has focused preconditions and outcomes. Instead, the authors explore the content of these events. The goal of the paper is to check the plausibility of tentative thesis - that mass violence can be perceived through a rationalist framework
Summary/Theory/Argument:
Traditional explanations for why insurgent groups choose to engage is mass violence have focused primarily on ideology as the main explanatory factor. The authors argue that, counter to traditional accounts, mass violence against civilians is strategic with aims of maximizing civilian support. They sketch a theoretical framework for the analysis of civil wars to see how it fares in one particular case: insurgent violence in Algeria.
Method/Finding:
Focus on insurgent violence in Algeria in 1996 during the civil war, which started in 1992 after the Algerian Military (Incumbents) “aborted” the parliamentary election and terminated democracy
- This deprived the Islamic Salvation Front (FIS) of a sweeping victory and they eventually become outlawed insurgents that formed into two groups - the Islamic Salvation Army (AIS) and the GIA (which is believed to have contributed to most of the Massacres.
Generalized out to other countries at the end of the paper.
They find that Massacres tend to happen under conditions of fragmented rule, support for the incumbent state, and escalating violence.
They were not random, but attacked specific neighborhoods
Families of sympathizers were left alone
Victims belonged to three groups
Local opponents who supported incumbents
People supporting competing insurgent groups
Former sympathizers who switched allegiance (most targeted this group)
Definitions:
Massacre
- Defined narrowly as large-scale, face-to-face violence against civilians targeted in groups and in the context of a civil war.
Violence
- Measure in it most basic form: homicide
Sears, David O., and Christia Brown. 2013. “Childhood and Adult Political Development.” Ch. 3 in Leonie Huddy, David O. Sears and Jack S. Levy, Eds., The Oxford Handbook of Political Psychology, 2nd edition. Oxford University Press.
Bumper Sticker:
“Experiences during early childhood are largey responsible for partisan predispositions and political leanings in adult life”
Purpose:
This chapter examines the life histories of political orientations as they evolve from early childhood through old age.
Summary/Theory/Argument:
Sears and Brown (2013) employ a life history perspective (framework) to understanding how political orientations evolve across the human lifespan. The use of this framework provides some helpful insights:
Is addresses the constant tension between continuity and change as played out throughout an individuals lifespan
It helps us to understand the origins of orientations that are politically consequential among adults, whether concerning politics specifically or intergroup relations.
Findings:
This review has suggested that partisan predispositions are most likely to be acquired in early development, if not quite as uniformly early as originally thought.
The authors suggest that this is due the role of “time” which is treated as an independent variable that takes three forms
The persisting effects of early experiences
The major events or “the times” that characterize the environment an individual has experienced
The life stages of development - children, adolescents, adults all have different cognitive capabilities
Based on the various ways fo thinking about time, the authors pose four alternative models of the full political life cycel that are often contrasted in the literature and which speak to Campbell’s conception of party identification being shaped by early learning behavior, persistence, and later influence on voting behavior.
four alternative models of the full political life cycle have often been contrasted:
(1) persistence: the residues of preadult learning persist through life;
(2) a variant, impressionable years: orientations are particularly susceptible to influence in late adolescence and early adulthood, but tend to stabilize thereafter
(3) its major alternative, lifelong openness: individuals remain open to influence throughout later life, including by “the times”
(4) life cycle: people show distinctive specific propensities at different stages of life (this one is particularly difficult to pin down)
Definitions:
The Life-History Perspective
- a theoretical framework within political science that draws on insights from biology, psychology, and sociology to understand the trajectory of political systems over time.
Additional Things:
- The life history perspective of political development is a theoretical framework within political science that draws on insights from biology, psychology, and sociology to understand the trajectory of political systems over time. This perspective views political development as akin to the life cycle of an organism, with distinct stages of growth, maturation, decline, and potential renewal.
Key features of the life history perspective of political development include:
Stages of Development: Similar to biological life cycles, political systems are seen to progress through various stages of development. These stages may include periods of consolidation, expansion, crisis, and transformation. Each stage is characterized by specific challenges, opportunities, and dynamics.
Adaptation to Environmental Pressures: Just as organisms adapt to their environments to survive and thrive, political systems must adapt to changing societal, economic, and environmental conditions. This may involve institutional reforms, policy adjustments, or shifts in political strategies to address new challenges or opportunities.
Resource Allocation and Trade-offs: The life history perspective emphasizes the importance of resource allocation and trade-offs in political development. Political systems must allocate scarce resources, such as financial capital, human capital, and political capital, among competing priorities and objectives. Decisions about resource allocation may have long-term implications for the trajectory of political development.
Reproduction and Inheritance: Political systems often inherit institutional legacies, cultural norms, and social structures from previous generations. These inherited traits shape the opportunities and constraints faced by contemporary political actors and influence the trajectory of political development. Similarly, political systems may reproduce themselves through processes of institutional continuity, elite reproduction, and socialization.
Variation and Diversity: Just as biological organisms exhibit variation and diversity within and across species, political systems display variation and diversity in their structures, institutions, and practices. The life history perspective recognizes that different political systems may follow distinct trajectories of development due to historical legacies, cultural norms, and contextual factors.
Adaptive Responses to External Shocks: Political systems may face external shocks and disruptions, such as economic crises, wars, or natural disasters, that necessitate adaptive responses. The life history perspective emphasizes the importance of resilience and flexibility in responding to external shocks and maintaining political stability and legitimacy.
Partisanship is apparently a really salient predictor of mate choice lol
Week 10: Spring Break (NO CLASS!)
Week 12: Trust in Government/Support for Democracy
Anderson, Christopher J., and Christine A. Guillory. 1997. “Political Institutions and Satisfaction with Democracy: A Cross-National Analysis of Consensus and Majoritarian Systems.” American Political Science Review 91(1): 66-82.
Bailard, Catie Snow. 2012. “A Field Experiment on the Internet’s Effect in an African Election: Savvier Citizens, Disaffected Voters, or Both?” Journal of Communication 62(2): 330-344.
I like this one a lot.
Research Question:
Does the internet influence evaluations of the government and motivate people to organize politically?
Contributions to Literature:
This paper tests the internet’s effect at a more antecedent and foundational stage of political behavior. Past literature looks at the internet’s influence after people have already moved to act and organize.
The second contribution is methodological. A field experiment can provide direct causal tests. This is a first for this body of research.
Theory:
Why would the internet have an effect on political organization?
“Mirror-Holding” - The internet enables more people to mirror hold. What does this mean?
The Internet holds up a mirror for users to better discern and reflect on how their government is actually performing.
The global nature of the Internet also opens more panoramic windows that better enable individuals to view how governments function in other countries, particularly the high-functioning democracies that tend to be most visible on the Internet. This provides users with a more realistic and globally consistent scale by which to make comparative evaluations about their own government’s performance.
The internet provides more information to citizens, from a broader range of perspectives, than would otherwise be the case-thus improving the capacity of citizens to make more informed evaluations of their governments.
- Reminds me a bit of Kevin Munger supply and demand perspective of youtube.
By providing a venue to publicly document government’s failure or abuses, often coupled with pictures and videos, individuals more readily link their personal experiences to a much larger, pervasive, and entrenched national trend.
Hypothesis:
This the internet will provide a more robust and different set of information regarding the integrity of the Tanzania election compared to that provided by the traditional media.
Method:
Field Experiment:
Focus: 2010 Tanzania elections
Why?: 2010 elections were not deemed fully free and fair?
- Uchaguzi (an internet platform) allowed people to create a visual map of where election abuses were reported - allowing citizens to view and reflect on it.
Unit of analysis: Tanzanian individuals
Subjects were recruited in person at several congregation points in the community of Morogoro. Morgogoro is 120 miles away from the economic capital. 200k population. 200 names were collected. Using random assignment, 70 respondents were given the internet treatment and 70 respondents were given the no-internet control condition.
Subjects were asked to meet at internet cafes. Pre Surveys were given. Individuals then had access to the internet at the cafe for 2 months. Control group was not given internet time but would gain it after the experiment was over. No restrictions were put on how respondents used the internet. After 2 months, respondents were contacted again for a post survey.
Results:
Treatment group had less faith in a fair election and believed the recount was less fair.
Users with facebook accounts were more likely to think the election was unfair.
Treatment was also more likely to trust the police force.
***Internet users who became more aware of electoral abuses also may have become less likely to believe that their vote mattered as a consequence. While some protested, others simply stayed home.
- The internet may be a double edged sword.
The internet can alter the cost-benefit calculus of political behavior by expanding the range of information individuals have regarding their government’s actual performance.
Members of the disaffected Internet group were less likely to vote.
Showing internet is not the amazing positive force we thought it was
- This is obvious now but in 2010 not so much!
Stone’s Thoughts:
I love this article! The theory section regarding how the internet influences political behavior is really intuitive. I think I have a good understanding for how the internet influenced all of us and how it culminated into Trump and the polarization across the world. Let me (attempt) to explain my perspective.
For the masses: The internet increased communication and information (duh). As Bailard points out, this changes the cost-benefit analysis for individuals to FORM political opinions. In essence, it becomes easier to engage in politics because it reduces the cost to do so. Information can be obtained so readily and easy that people can engage and it seems Bailard shows this to be the case. As a result, the SUPPLY of voters/individuals interested in politics, increases.
For elites: The internet provides a new platform for people to engage in politics. Prior to the internet, the barrier to become an elite was much more difficult. The internet democratized who can be an elite. Youtube, facebook, etc. provided a space for anyone to become an elite. This increased the SUPPLY of elites (look at Kevin Munger’s work). The greater supply of elites introduced greater VARIATION in ideology of the elite class (this is how you get polarization to increase as more and more people are expressing different viewpoints). The increased variation of ideology in the elite class spills over into the information and cues they provide to the masses. Because it is easier to be an elite and share information, the masses now have greater access to the variation in perspectives. In short, there used to be a strong barrier towards becoming an elite, perhaps gated by education, money, network, etc; however, the internet basically allows anyone to become an elite and provide cues to people.
There is a greater SUPPLY of informed voters, SUPPLY of elites, SUPPLY of information and that is what might be driving our polarized epoch.
- Thank you for coming to my Ted Talk.
Mishler, William, and Richard Rose. 2001. “What are the origins of Political Trust? Testing Institutional and Cultural Theories in Post-communist Societies.” Comparative Political Studies 34(1): 30-62.
Bumper Sticker:
“Micro-level institutional arrangements are the source of political trust.”
Research Question:
What is the source of political trust?
Purpose:
Understanding how trust begins is important for the consolidation of new democracies. There are competing explanations for the sources of political trust. Some hypotheses stress exogenous determinants (these are considered cultural theories) while others stress endogenous determinants (these are considered institutional theories). Both can take micro- and macro-level forms. The authors set out to assess which determinants are stronger.
Summary/Theory/Argument:
(National Culture): Trust in political institutions varies between countries rather than among individuals according to historically rooted, national experiences embedded in interpersonal structure.
(Individual socialization): Trust in institutions varies within and across countries according to individuals’ trust in others as shaped by their places in the social structure.
(Government performance): Trust in institutions varies across rather than within countries in proportion to the success of government policies and the character of political institutions.
(Individual evaluations): Trust in institutions varies within and across countries in accordance with both individuals attitudes and values and the social and economic positions individuals occupy.
Findings:
Strongly support the superiority of institutional explanations (endogenous) of the origins of political trust, especially microlevel explanations, while providing little support for either micro-cultural or macro-cultural explanations.
The effects of macro-political and economic performance on trust are indirect and mediated at the micro level by an individual’s value-laden perceptions
Contrary to cultural theories, interpersonal trust varies widely within societies and has little appreciable effect on institutional trust at either the aggregate or individual levels
micro-institutional hypothesis (Hypothesis 4) is confirmed, and the other hypotheses (Hypothesis 1 through Hypothesis 3) are rejected.
Building trust: (p. 56) Trust can be nurtured by improving the conduct and performance of political institutions. Governments can generate public trust the old-fashioned way: They can earn it by responding promptly and effectively to public priorities, rooting out corrupt practices, and protecting new freedoms (Hetherington, 1998, reaches similar conclusions). Political institutions also can earn trust through economic policies that promise and ultimately provide a better material future for the country as a whole.
Methods:
Data - data from 10 post-Communist countries in Eastern and Central Europe and the former Soviet Union.
- Aggregate data on economic and political performance are combined with survey data on interpersonal and political trust, political socialization experiences, and individual evaluations of national performance.
Survey data (p. 40) analyzed here come from the fifth New Democracies Barometer (NDB V), organized by the Paul Lazarsfeld Society, Vienna, and the seventh New Russia Barometer (NRB VII), organized by the Centre for the Study of Public Policy at the University of Strathclyde.
NDB interviews were conducted between January 1998 and May 1998 in seven Central and East European countries—Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Slovenia—and in two successor states of the former Soviet Union, Belarus and Ukraine.
Professional survey firms conducted face-to-face interviews using national probability samples of approximately 1,000 in each country.
In addition, NRB interviews were conducted in Russia by the All-Russian Center for Public Opinion in March 1998 and April 1998 using a multistage national probability sample that yielded 1,904 face-to-face interviews
To test the effects of both national context and individual differences
Pooled the survey data from the 10 countries in a single multinational file of 11,499 respondents.
Each country was weighted equally as having 1,000 cases, and a variety of macro-contextual and aggregate performance variables were added to the merged data set so that respondents could be analyzed in terms of both their individual attributes and their national contexts.
Institutional trust was measured using the question “There are many different institutions in the country, for example, the government, courts, police, civil servants. Please show me on this 7-point scale, where 1 represents great distrust and 7 represents trust, how much is your personal trust in each of the following institutions?”
Then were asked “how much do you trust most people you meet?”
When testing micro theories
Five proxies for political socialization are included in the model: age, education, gender, town size, and church attendance.
Five political performance measures also are used, including the aggregate index of political corruption and micro-level perceptions of personal freedom, government fairness, political corruption, and government responsiveness to citizen influence.
Definitions:
Cultural Theories - view trust as exogenous to political institutions and are a basic character trait learned early in life.
Micro-Theories - focus on differences in individual socialization experiences as sources of significant variation in political trust within as well as between societies.
Macro-Theories - emphasize the homogenizing tendencies of national traditions and make little allowance for variation in trust among individuals within societies
Institutional Theories - view trust as endogenous and as a consequence of institutional performance.
Micro-Theories - emphasize the aggregate performance of institutions in such matters as promoting growth, governing effectively, and avoiding corruption.
- The outputs of institutional trust are assumed to determine individual responses.
Macro-Theories - emphasize that individual evaluations of institutional performance are conditioned by individual tastes and experiences
- Such as whether a person thinks that political integrity or economic growth is more important and whether that individual personally has experienced the effects of corruption or the benefits of economic growth.
Macro-Theories - emphasize that trust is a collective or group property broadly shared by all members of a society
Micro-Theories - hold that trust varies among individuals within a society based on differences in socialization and social background, political and economic experiences, or individual perceptions and evaluations.
Lifetime-Learning Model - A model that integrates early-life socialization and adult learning, thereby allowing direct empirical comparisons.
Abstract:
Popular trust in political institutions is vital to democracy, but in post-Communist countries, popular distrust for institutions is widespread, and prospects for generating increased political trust are uncertain given disagreements over its origins. Cultural theories emphasizing exogenous determinants of trust compete with institutional theories emphasizing endogenous influences, and both can be further differentiated into micro and macro variants. Competing hypotheses drawn from these theories are tested using data from 10 post-Communist countries in Eastern and Central Europe and the former Soviet Union. Aggregate data on economic and political performance are combined with survey data on interpersonal and political trust, political socialization experiences, and individual evaluations of national performance. Results strongly support the superiority of institutional explanations of the origins of political trust, especially microlevel explanations, while providing little support for either micro-cultural or macro-cultural explanations. This encourages cautious optimism about the potential for nurturing popular trust in new democratic institutions.
Mutz, Diana C., and Byron Reeves. 2005. “The New Videomalaise: Effects of Televised Incivility on Political Trust.” American Political Science Review 99 (1):1-15.
Bumper Sticker:
Rude TV debates depress political trust!
IV:
Incivility between political opponents on TV
DV:
Trust in government and politicians
Research Question:
Does televised political incivility harm levels of trust in government and politicians?
Hypothesis:
When political actors violate interpersonal social norms on television, viewers react as they would if they were witnessing the same interaction in real life; they react negatively to incivility.
Data:
- 3 survey experiments with pre-test, experiment, and post-test
Methods:
Respondents put into 1 of 3 experimental groups and difference of means test conducted on pre- and post-test survey results after respondents watched fictional TV program of political debate with either civil or uncivil exchange:
Experiment 1 subjects randomly assigned to civil or uncivil conditions (n = 67)
Experiment 2 included a 3rd control condition where subjects didn’t watch any political TV (n = 155)
Experiment 3 used within-subjects design where all were assigned to both civil and uncivil conditions in random order to understand process of influence
Political trust measured from National Election Studies under rubric of support for the political system
Findings:
- Hypotheses confirmed! Individuals are negatively impacted by uncivil exchanges on televised political discourse as evidenced by lower trust in government on surveys following exposure.
Questions:
Mutz and Reeves write that “when political actors engage in TV interactions that violate the norms for everyday, face-to-face discourse, they reaffirm viewers’ sense that politicians cannot be counted on to obey the same norms for social behavior by which ordinary citizens abide” (2). Does this work in the opposite direction? If politicians began treating each other respectfully on televised debates, would we expect to see an increase in political trust and that would translate into greater political participation?
Related to the question above – if we assume that academic literature is the dominant civil medium for research-backed discourse, and that this discourse is important for policy change, institutional stability, and informed public participation in politics, how do we amplify its reach?
If this study were repeated today, would the results hold? Do we agree that people expect political actors to act civilly toward each other? And if not, is this partly due to the dwindling approval ratings overall of our politicians and our political institutions?
General Notes:
Television and political trust
Robinson popularized term “videomalaise” in 1975 to refer to attitudes that resulted from watching television news
Evidence supporting the causal claim that television is responsible for low levels of political trust has been limited
- Claims have broadened into general critique of political journalism
Main emphasis of research has been on the extent to which televised politics heightens the importance of personality characteristics in general evaluations of candidates
Candidates’ personal qualities more important to voters who obtained political news from TV (Keeter 1987)
TV primes people to rely more on personality perceptions when evaluating candidates (Druckman 2003)
Social psychology theories of human-media interaction suggest that TV political disagreements would exacerbate the “intensification of feeling” Lippmann described in 1925
“When political actors engage in TV interactions that violate the norms for everyday, face-to-face discourse, they reaffirm viewers’ sense that politicians cannot be counted on to obey the same norms for social behavior by which ordinary citizens abide” (2)
Focus of this study is TV b/c it’s the dominant medium
Theoretical basis for videomalaise
To trust = to assume that a person or institution will “observe the rules of the game” (Citrin and Muste 1999)
People expect political actors who appear on television to abide by the same social norms acknowledged by ordinary Americans
People react negatively to incivility (even if it’s on TV)
Experience of political conflict on TV substantially different from real life
Need for politeness is particularly great when expressing controversial views (Kingwell 1995)
Politeness and respect toward individuals involved in a legal conflict enhances their perceptions of fair treatment (Tyler 1990)
Television world provides uniquely intimate perspective on conflicts
When social norms for civility are violated on TV, viewers’ intimate perspective intensifies an already negative reaction to incivility
Reeves & Nass (1996) show that when motion appears on TV, physiological responses are the same as when motion occurs in the immediate environment – the human brain hasn’t evolved quickly enough to respond in rational ways to technologies such as TV
When encountering differences of opinion in person, people tend to downplay differences and maintain a polite, cordial atmosphere
In contrast, TV emphasizes conflict and strong differences of opinion to enhance dramatic value and attract viewers
TV is also a highly intimate medium
Central hypothesis: This violation of social norms should cause negative reactions toward politicians and government
People expect others to obey social norms and evaluate them less favorably when they don’t
Given that the normative expectation is one of civility, this influence should be primarily a function of negative reactions to incivility rather than positive reaction s to civility
Further hypothesize that TV viewers will respond negatively to incivility on TV due to largely gut-level, emotional reactions to violations of social norms rather than a cognitive awareness of excessive conflict
Study Design
Problems with validity and reliability of self-reported media exposure (Price & Zaller 1993), so experimental design used
Central manipulation: the extent to which politicians exchanged political viewpoints in a manner that violates the typical norms governing face-to-face political conflict
Used adults and undergraduates
Exposed viewers to systematically different versions of 4 different political disagreements drawn from a larger pool
Manipulated extent of civility and politeness w/o altering political content
Expectation that when dissonant views were presented in an uncivil fashion, they would encourage more negative, distrustful attitudes toward politics and politicians
Professional actors hired to play roles of 2 congressional candidates with TV studio/political talk show mock program
Teleprompters used to hep actors adhere closely to a script
Candidates assigned opposing views on each issue and interaction was to be civl or uncivil
Experiment 1: free trade, mental health insurance, Internet privacy regulation, and NASA funding
Experiment 2: tobacco regulation, taxation of retail sales on the Internet, public service experience, and free trade
Experiment 3: tobacco regulation, Internet taxes, repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act, and public service experience
- Each edited to 5 min in length
2 versions of each exchange taped
- Candidates expressed exactly same position in same words in both versions, offered same arguments, but civil exchanges were VERY civil and uncivil exchanges took personal jabs, raised voices, and never apologized (as well as rude nonverbal reactions)
Figure 1 shows results: candidates in uncivil versions of issue exchanges consistently perceived as less polite, more quarrelsome, more emotional, agitated, and hostile
- 2 null findings: no perceived ideological differences in a candidate’s stand in civil vs. uncivil condition
Procedures
Participants sat alone in a room w/a comfy couch and overstuffed chair, coffee table, and 32-inch TV
After consent, they filled out a pretest questionnaire
Then viewed 20 min of TV program featuring same scripted disagreements on 4 different issues
Then filled out posttest questionnaire
- Subjects in experiment #2 not told hypothesis in order to facilitate follow-up interviews by phone
Experiment 1 subjects randomly assigned to civil or uncivil conditions (n = 67)
Experiment 2 included a 3rd control condition where subjects didn’t watch any political TV (n = 155)
Control group included to determine whether differences between civil and uncivil condition swerve due to an elevation of political trust in the civil condition, a decrease in trust in the uncivil condition, or some combo
This control group filled out same pre- and posttest questionnaires but watched a non-political program
Experiment 3 used within-subjects design where all were assigned to both civil and uncivil conditions in random order to understand process of influence
Political trust measured from National Election Studies under rubric of support for the political system
Results
Data analyzed by testing difference of mean levels of trust in 2 conditions in experiment 1; all 3 trust measures significantly influenced negatively by uncivil exchange (see Figure 2)
People differentiated between the importance of public conflict and the civility of that conflict
Uncivil versions perceived to be more entertaining than civil versions
Orhan, Yunus Emre. 2022. “The relationship between affective polarization and democratic backsliding: comparative evidence.” Democratization 29(4): 714-735.
Week 13: Information/Knowledge/Communication
Gordon, Stacy B., and Gary M. Segura. 1997. “Cross-national Variation in the Political Sophistication of Individuals: Capability or Choice?” Journal of Politics 59(1): 126-147.
Bumper Sticker:
Voter sophistication is a product of individual measures * country context & structures!
IV:
institutional and contextual variables
DV:
individual measures of political sophistication
Research Question:
What if measures of political sophistication reflect performance rather than capability? What if our dismal assessments of the individual capabilities of citizens were based on measures driven, in part, by the reasonable decisions of those very same citizens, rather than on innate capabilities alone?
Hypothesis:
Citizen capability and choice are funneled through contextual and structural elements in a society to produce political sophistication.
Data:
- 1989 Cross-national Euro-Barometer survey data from 12 pre-1995 EU nations
Methods:
Ordinary Least Squares regression model
Findings:
Considerable and significant differences in citizen political sophistication across nations due to contextual factors shaping availability, usefulness, and cost political info.
Citizen performance varies from country to country
Partisan and electoral systems that increase uncertainty of how election outcomes will be reflected in representative institutions or muddy the party-policy linkages in the minds of the voters act as strong disincentives for active accumulation and usage of accurate political info
General Notes:
Literature on political sophistication offers 2 competing visions of the electorate:
Mass public is not well versed in matters of politics
Conclusions about voters not valid
Measurement strategies/instruments not good
Conclusions of first view overlook useful info voters do have and use
Authors agree with 2nd view and seek to operationalize definition of sophistication
- Individual levels of sophistication are the product of choices driven by a contextual incentive structure
Classic view: Converse (1964) – voter opinions not ideologically constrained across time or issues; this is basically stating that voters don’t understand politics
- Citizens can’t hold reps accountable if they don’t understand the system
More generous view rejects this
Measures used to estimate level of info and integration crude and unreliable (Achen 1975; Erikson 1979; Luskin 1987)
Measures systematically underestimate levels of info and cognitive capacity among citizens (Nie & Andersen 1974)
Individuals may not be politically sophisticated but democracy is safe b/c sophistication is a “collective phenomenon” (Feld & Grofman 1988)
Collective public opinion measures stable and consistent (Page & Shapiro 1992; Stimson 1991)
Even in absence of high levels of info, voters may successfully use scant amounts of info to develop specific issue positions; they can take cues from
affective orientation toward relevant actors (Brady & Sniderman 1985)
Political environment (Zaller 1992)
General orientations toward politics or specific issue areas (Feldman 1988 & 1989; Peffley & Hurwitz 1993)
Individuals understand issues that are personally salient (Neuman 1986)
Recognized difference in stability and consistency between opinion on ‘easy’ and ‘hard’ issues (Carmines & Stimson 1989)
- “While many citizens lack extensive political information, ‘assessing voters by civics exams misses the many things that voters do know, and the many ways they can do without the facts that the civics tradition assumes they should know’ (Popkin 1991, 20; emphasis in the original)” (128).
Public’s performance on measures of sophistication not sufficient to illustrate political capabilities
Shortcomings may be the product of systems – and individual choices structured by those systems
Current 3 components to measure sophistication:
Means (cognitive capacity)
Motive (incentives toward collecting and using accurate political info)
Opportunity (availability of aforementioned info)
How do we measure this accurately then?
Capabilities
Smart people can and do have more info and more accurate info
Individual-level characteristics have an effect on sophistication
Education
Income
Occupational status
Media usage
These variables may be the best proxies to control for different dimensions of individual capabilities
The more highly educated may have been indoctrinated into the standard belief system/dominant social ideology
Being at a higher ed or socioeconomic status may reduce costs of collecting political info
Choices
As opportunities to get info become more scarce, motivation to get it must increase; thus, several factors will structure these choices:
Party system
Individuals in multiparty system would be more motivated to collect info b/c opportunity to do so is greater
Downs’ (1957) median voter theorem tells us parties will try to differentiate themselves from each other to mobilize support – increasing available info
This effect declines as number of parties get significantly higher
Electoral system
Nationally competitive elections will increase political sophistication by increasing motivation
Parliamentary societies lower cost of political info b/c parties’ positions are stable
Compulsory voting increases turnout and may increase sophistication
Data and Analysis
Sophistication: using 1989 Euro-Barometer postelection survey in 12 nations of pre-1995 EU by calculating absolute distances between respondent’s placement of each of his or her society’s political parties on a 10-point ideological scale and the mean placement of those parties by the remaining respondents from that society
Compute a mean across these distances that equals the inaccuracy of the respondent’s info using the society mean as the baseline
Low scores = high sophistication so they invert this measure
DV sophistication 0-9 w/9 representing extremely high level of sophistication
Iyengar, Shanto, et al. 2010. “Cross-National versus Individual-Level Differences in Political Information: A Media Systems Perspective.” Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties. 20(3): 291-309.
Bumper Sticker:
The media have a significant impact on informing the electorate!
Research Question:
Does the structure, funding model, and political accountability of the news media in a country impact the knowledge of the electorate? Does this knowledge have varying cross-national effects?
IV:
News coverage & political interest
DV:
Political & news knowledge
Hypothesis:
News media governed by supply and demand forces that have real-world implications:
When news coverage is informative and frequently encountered, even less attentive citizens become informed
When media environment is relatively barren of political content or when there is an abundance of entertainment programs that compete with news, acquisition of info becomes challenging and limited to individuals who self-select into the news audience
Data:
Coded news media coverage in 2007 in 4 countries: US, UK, Denmark, & Finland
- “Hard” vs “soft” news and “international” vs “domestic” news
28-question online survey to 1,000 representative respondents in each country about easy and difficult questions over hard, soft, international, and domestic news
Methods:
- Difference of mean scores and OLS variable effects
Findings:
- Countries with least regulated, market-oriented media provide least amount of “hard” news and their populations score lowest on surveys.
General Notes:
Standard predictors of political knowledge have been political interest, media attentiveness, education and other equivalent measures of political motivation
The authors propose a context-dependent approach to the study of political info
Individual-level motivational factors vary across contexts
When news coverage is informative and frequently encountered, even less attentive citizens become informed
When media environment is relatively barren of political content or when there is an abundance of entertainment programs that compete with news, acquisition of info becomes challenging and limited to individuals who self-select into the news audience
- Level of info affected jointly by demand and supply variables
Research design
Content analysis of broadcast news sources and a survey measuring public awareness to investigate cross-national differences in 3 different knowledge gaps in the US, UK, Denmark, & Finland
Variation in media system type by the 4 countries selected:
Denmark & Finland closest to relatively pure public service model + subsidized “guardianship” model; expectation is that most regulated systems will have highest level of hard news content
US exemplifies pure market-based regime + social responsibility tradition; expectation is that ratio of hard to soft news will be significantly lower here
- I feel attacked by the authors’ statement that “American media are overwhelmingly in private hands, its public television network (PBS) is under-funded and achieves a trivial audience share” [emphasis mine].
Britain represents a hybrid
Content Analysis
US: 2 highest-rated network newscasts (ABC & NBC News)
Britain: BBC1 and ITV
Denmark: DR1 and TV2
Finland: YLE1 and MTV3
Monitored for 4 weeks during March-April 2007
Stories classified by trained student or research assistant coders
- Disaggregated content elements compromising hard/soft news distinctions and then coding the sequential categories:
Classify news reports in terms of topical area.
Politics, public administration, the economy, and science = “hard”
Celebrities, entertainment, and sport = “soft”
Classify mode of treatment.
Public good or issues about public policy and administration = “hard”
Human interest = “soft”
Classify either as domestic or overseas events & presence of international or regional organization (UN or EU)
Survey Design
28 multiple-choice questions to reflect citizens’ awareness of both hard and soft news and their familiarity with domestic vs. international subject matter
“Easy” and “difficult” questions
Administered online
Minimizes sampling bias through use of sample matching featuring dual samples – one strictly probabilistic and based on an offline populations, and a second non-probabilistic based on a large panel of online respondents
- Each online respondent selected to provide mirror image of corresponding respondent selected by conventional Random Digital Dialling (RDD) methods
1,000 respondents from each online panel, all over the age of 18
Results
Cross-National Differences in News Content
Market-based system of US and UK’s mixed system offer lowest level of hard news coverage (Table 1)
No cross-national differences in domestic vs. international news
Cross-National Differences in Information
Means corresponding to average proportion of respondents in each country who provided correct answers to questions about domestic, international, hard, and soft news (Table 2)
Americans less informed about hard news
Americans slightly ahead of Britain of domestic knowledge, but both trail Scandinavian countries by a large margin
Measure of motivational or demand-side factors on hard and soft news knowledge and international and domestic knowledge (Table 3)
Motivation = index of political involvement
Coefficients for substantial cross-national differences unaffected by controls for interest, education, exposure to TV news, and gender
Mutz, Diana C. 2006. Hearing the Other Side: Deliberative versus Participatory Democracy. Cambridge University Press. Ch. 1&2.
Research Question:
What kind of relationships allow political conversation with those who do not share our viewpoint? Overarching Can deliberative and participatory democracy cohabitate?
Bumper Sticker:
Chap 2 Strong tie network, low deliberative possibility Overarching High participation, low deliberation/ High deliberation, low participation
Type:
Data from several national American survey sources on networks of political discussion: 1992 American component of the Cross National Election Project (CNEP) surbey, the 2000 ANES and a 1996 survey funded by the Spencer Foundation and gathered ny the University of Wisconsin-Madison Survey Research Center, supplemented with experimental evidence from the World Values Surveys and additional countries data in the CNEP.
DV:
Cross-cutting poltical conversations
IV:
The strength of network
Hypothesis:
The strength of a network affect the capacity of individuals within the network to engage in cross cutting deliberative democracy.
Findings:
Americans overwhelmingly sort themselves into homogenous political sphere, even in terms of context which should be an exogenous variable (contexts are structurally imposed, networks are individually constructed (Huckfelt and Sprague, 1995)
The one place that might provide heterogenous political conversation and the weaker ties is the workplace
More work should be done on workplace context
Winkler, Stephen. 2021. “Media’s Influence on LBGTQ Support Across Africa.” British Journal of Political Science 51(2): 807-826.
Bumper Sticker:
“The type of medium one uses to get information can impact attitudes towards LGBTQ+ individuals.”
Research Question:
Does media consumption explain individual support for homosexuality? If so, how?
Summary/Theory/Argument:
Develops a theory that accounts for the variety of ways in which pro- and anti- gay-rights actors engage with the media, which generates clear expectations about how different types of media create distinct effects on public opinion of LGBTQs.
The author argues that increased overall media consumption enhances support for LGBTQs, but that this effect is driven by consumption of newspaper, internet and social media. This is because government censorship of queer content is often directed at television programs that contain positive representations of LGBTQs.
The media impacts public opinion of the LGBTQ+ community through (1) exposing individuals to positive representation and (2) exposing individuals to new information in general
Findings:
Different types of media produce distinct effects on public opinions of LGBTQ+ people
Radio and television have no significant effect on pro-gay attitudes
Newspapers, internet, or social media have a positive effect on support
These effects are conditional on censorship of queer representation from certain mediums
Show that governments proudly publicize their crackdowns on queer content in TV
78 % of respondents report negative attitudes towards homosexuality.
- However, individuals who consume more media overall are 4–8 %t more likely to express pro-gay beliefs.
Through content analysis of radio, newspaper and the internet, provide preliminary evidence that the mechanisms driving these effects is increased access and exposure to positive LGBTQ representation.
Method:
Looks at media consumption across thirty-three African countries.
multi-methods approach, which combines cross-sectional survey data with content analysis and descriptive data from across Africa
- Cross-national survey data from Afrobarometer Round 6 conducted in 2014 and 2015.
Estimates 6 binomial logits
Country fixed effects and district-clustered standard errors help to account for country and sub-national differences
- One to look at the impact of an individuals aggregate score across, and then one for each of the 5 mediums
Results hold when replicated using OLS and ordered-probit models
IV:
- questions in the survey that ask how often the respondent gets their news from five different sources: radio, television, newspaper, internet and social media.
DV:
- primary dependent variable is a question in the survey that asks how the respondent would feel about having a ‘homosexual’ as a neighbor
Abstract:
Political leaders across Africa frequently accuse the media of promoting homosexuality, while activists often use the media to promote pro-LGBTQ (lesbian, gay, bisexual, transgender and queer) narratives. Despite extensive research on how the media affects public opinion, including studies that show how exposure to certain information can increase support of LGBTQs, there is virtually no research on how the media influences attitudes towards LGBTQs across Africa. This study develops a theory that accounts for actors’ mixed approach to the media and shows how different types of media create distinct effects on public opinion of LGBTQs. Specifically, the study finds that radio and television have no, or a negative, significant effect on pro-gay attitudes, whereas individuals who consume more newspapers, internet or social media are significantly more likely to support LGBTQs (by approximately 2 to 4 per cent). The author argues that these differential effects are conditional on censorship of queer representation from certain mediums. The analysis confirms that the results are not driven by selection effects, and that the relationship is unique to LGBTQ support but not other social attitudes. The results have important implications, especially given the growing politicization of same-sex relations and changing media consumption habits across Africa.
Week 14: Electoral Participation
Aguilar, Edwin Eloy, and Alexander Pacek. 2000. “Macroeconomic Conditions, Voter Turnout, and the Working Class/Economically Disadvantaged Party Vote in Developing Countries.” Comparative Political Studies 33(8): 995-1017.
Bumper Sticker:
The lower class mobilizes in developing countries during economic downturns!
Research Question:
To what extent and in what manner do fluctuations in voter turnout affect support for parties with working-class/lower status concerns in the developing world? In what manner does the macroeconomy play a mitigating role in this relationship?
IV:
economic downturn * voter turnout
DV:
party support (working-class/economically disadvantaged party vote)
Hypothesis:
In developing countries, during economic downturns, more of the working class and disadvantaged class will turn out to vote.
In those elections, political parties who are oriented towards these classes will increase their vote share compared to previous elections, all else equal.
Data:
- Pooled time-series data for 10 countries in Latin America, Caribbean, Africa, & Asia
Methods:
- Regression analysis
Findings:
- Both hypotheses confirmed!
General Notes:
Authors seek to understand relationship between voter turnout, macroeconomic conditions, and support for political parties w/explicit appeals to working class/disadvantaged in developing democracies
WCED parties = political parties for working class/economically disadvantaged
A number of does support idea that economy affects voter turnout in the developing world (Pacek & Radcliff, 1995b; Radcliff, 1992)
Turnout and party support
Higher levels of turnout benefit left parties electorally in advanced industrial nations (Crewe 1981)
Lower status/economically disadvantaged citizens who are the traditional left party constituents vote at lower and more variable rates tan their better-off counterparts
Lower status voters more marginal or “peripheral” b/c there’s a lower probability that they’ll vote – varies each election
- Left parties should demonstrate varying support as turnout fluctuates
“Class bias” in voter turnout = ratio of lower-class to upper-class voters participating; considerable class bias exists in their sample of countries. “Few studies outside the United States have examined the extent to which this measure may vary across time and why. A simple correlation between class bias scores and voter turnout for the same years across a sample of developing countries produces a score of –.78; higher class bias scores, indicating a greater discrepancy between upper-class and lower-class voting, are associated with lower levels of turnout” (997-998, emphasis mine).
Cross-national studies on this concept have lagged
Pacek and Radcliff’s 1995c cross-national study of elections in 19 industrial democracies from 1950-1990 found that left parties’ share of the vote increased by almost one third of a percentage point for every percentage point increase in turnout
Alford Indices measure class voting from national surveys
- “If [disadvantaged/working] classes tend to support the spectrum of parties with specific appeals toward them and generally vote less than those who are better off, then such parties should benefit from increases in turnout in a manner similar to the effect in advanced industrial societies” (999).
Selection criteria for WCED parties:
Examine class composition of political party specrum where survey data on party choice are available for an indication of which parties appeal primarily to the working and economically disadvantaged classes.
Examine the programmatic appeals and policy orientation of party types from various editions of Political Parties of the World and the Political Handbook of the World as well as individual website for political parties in countries where they focus.
Analysis
- Countries must meet the following criteria:
Country has held a series of relatively uninterrupted and competitive elections for which data are available.
Country has competing political parties with explicitly working- or lower-class appeals.
- Include each country’s initial postauthoritarian/postcolonial elections as they are also interested in transition
They use 7 developing democracies, 1 recent redemocratized case, and 3 historical examples (Chile 1958-1973, Sri Lanka 1952-1977, and Uruguay 1954-1971)
Regression of total percentage of vote for WCED parties on turnout in each election held in 10 developing countries
DV = parties’ combined percentage share of total vote from WCDE parties
Main IV = voter turnout (percentage of voting age population participating at election time)
Include autoregressive measure of previous party vote as control (moving average of WCED parties’ vote at times t – 1 and t – 2)
Dummy of election immediately following a boycott, postponement, or other irregularity
Pooled time-series data for national elections in 10 countries 1951-1990
- Dummy for each country excepting a reference category (fixed effects?)
Turnout = % of eligible voters casting ballots at time t
Lagged vote = expected party vote based on past voting patterns, calculated as the moving average of the WCED party vote at times t – 1 and t – 2
Election follows irregularity as dummy
countryn = dummy variables for each of the n – 1 countries in the study
- Table 2 shows the model fits the data really well (R2 of 0.75?!!)
The Macroeconomic Connection
Competing theories: Economic difficulties encourage people to seek political action to redress their grievances vs. Economic downturns may discourage voting (particularly the disadvantaged)
Economy-turnout effect contingent on region of the world being studied
Industrialized countries’ disadvantaged withdraw
Developing countries’ disadvantaged mobilize
- Why? Different nature of social welfare programs; no safety net
Table 3:
DV = % of population of voting age participating at time t
Main IV = election year % change in real per capita GDP
Table 4: adds
economy = the election year proportion change in real per capita national income
Lagged vote
Turnout
Economy* Party = interaction for election years when worker parties or coalitions are in power at the time of election X the state of the economy
Election follows irregularty
country
Aldrich, John H. 1993. “Rational Choice and Turnout.” American Journal of Political Science 37(1): 246-278.
Context:
Rational choice is very popular within the voter turnout field. At the time, people were moving away from RCT, Aldrich argues that it is still useful and can’t help us get closer to explaining why some people vote and others do not.
Goal:
Use rational choice to help us understand why some people vote and others do not.
- We can find variables that increase or decrease the likelihood of turning out. But they never in an absolute sense tell us above.
The Basic Model:
Preferences determine behavior
- Rat choice is about HOW those preferences determine behavior
A citizen’s preferences are realized in the outcome. We infer a voters preference through the action of who they vote for.
- Citizens’ preferences are transformed into utilities for outcomes when it matters how much the citizen prefers one outcome over another.
Conclusions of basic model:
Never vote for the less preferred candidate
If costs of voting are high, always abstain
If costs of voting are zero, then vote for A because voting for A dominates abstaining
If cost is between 0 and 5, the basic model is silent. Rational choice models of turnout differ over ways to handle these cases. See figure 1.
Rat Choice:
Rational choice theories are theories about the (expected) utility associated with outcomes generates or induces preferences for the particular actions at hand.
Fundamental is that rat choice argues that whichever outcome has a higher utility (1,0), the individual will choose actions to receive the higher utility outcome.
Actions are instruments to achieve outcomes
The action of voting is an instrument to achieve the desired outcome.
Cost of Voting:
Voting is not a costless action.
You have to obtain information, process it, decide what to do.
You have to go to the polls.
Some people say that not voting is costless
- Aldrich disagrees, rational abstainers must pay cost of deciding to vote or not.
Cost of voting is represented as, C
C > 0
When costs are high -> voter turnout decreases
- “When registration laws were passed, poll taxes were raised, or residency requirements were enacted, turnout fell.
Voters must still give some thought to what others might do. That factors into the voters choice to act.
If the voter thinks that their candidate will lose considerably, they probably will be less likely to vote.
- THE PROBLEM: voters do not know the situation they face.
The Calculus of Voting Model:
Initially developed by Downs and extended by Riker.
Controversial addition to the model. The term D
D represents the value of seeing democracy continue. If noe voted, Downs argued the political system would fail and thus some vote to ensure the continued vitality of democracy.
- Riker continues this - change it to “citizens duty”
Adding a D term is the same as subtracting a C term.
More of a sense of citizen duty can counter the cost of voting.
D does not change anything unless D > C.
CRITICAL INNOVATION TO CALCULUS OF VOTING MODEL:
Each person assigns a probability of the state of the world being true.
- The probability that one vote will make a difference.
Can be summed up through the equation:
R = PB + D - C
If R is positive, vote for candidate A (voters preferred candidate) if not, abstain.
R = Rewards
P = Probability of one vote breaking a tie
B = difference in utility for candidate A instead of B winning (diff in benefits)
D = citizen duty
C = cost of voting
Higher P = higher voter turnout
C, D, and B are strong predictors of turnout.
Problems with the Calculus of Voting model
D term is hotly debated
If you vote because “you wanted to” then voting is not instrumental towards an outcome.
- Rat choices are models of how one acts, given tastes. They are not models of where “taste” comes from.
The P term is not realistic. It is not reasonable to assume your vote will break a tie.
The Minimax Regret Model
Developed by Ferejohn and Fiorina
Reject completing the basic model.
They argue people’s ability to form probability assessments of the state of the world is basically too difficult and near impossible.
- If these probability assessments cannot be formed, they argue that the calculus of the voting model can not be used.
Instead of expected utility maximization, they propose a decision rule called minimax regret
Suppose a voter decided to abstain. Their preferred candidate loses by one vote. That voter would be regretful of their decision.
- Thus they measure the level of regret
Minimax regret refers to taking the action that yields the minimum of these maximum regrets.
- This model differs in what to do on the middle columns as seen in figure 1.
They argue their model is better than the calculus model and better predicts turnout more often.
Problems with the Minimax Regret Model:
P term is still an issue
P at least exist but is small
- Honestly this was a bit over my head. See page 259 - was confused.
Second issue is the wasted voting undermines the plausibility of minimax regret
A Third Approach - Game Theoretic Accounts:
Aldrich the other models have problems
Tho other models are based on decision theory
No one decision is assumed to affect the decisions of others.
- The decisions of others are highly aggregated
Game theory models do not make this mistake and assume that decisions are based on taking others’ decisions into explicit account.
Wait but aldrich says that problems in the calculus model are still at least somewhat present in game theory models
- ????????????????????
The Rationality of Turnout:
Turnout is cheap
Information gain is asymmetric
Elections differ in salience and impact.
Turnout is still a collective action problem BUT not a good example. Collective action problems typically assume importance because they are high-cost, high benefit decisions, where small P terms mean that the high B terms are substantially discounted. Turnout is a low cost, low benefit decision and she’s little light on most important collective action problems.
Strategic Politicians and Rational Choice Turnout:
A strategic politician explains why turnout is higher in close elections.
- More investment into close contests and this will be reflected in increasing levels of turnout.
Strategic politicians inform voters of the wasted-vote argument and convince at least some voters that it is sensible to act ast strategic voters
- I forget the name but there is a new book out that discusses how and where candidates go to campaign (physically). He basically finds that campaign events don’t really do anything other than increase turnout.
Blais, André. 2009. “Turnout in Elections.” OHPB. Ch. 33: 621-635.
Bumper Sticker:
Voter turnout variation in the aggregate and individually : not conclusive!
Research Question:
What is the state of the literature on aggregate and individual causes for voter turnout and its variation?
Type:
Review of the extensive research program on voter turnout in political science. It moves from research at the aggregate level, including why there is country level variation in voter turnout and finishes on individual level research review and why people vote.
IV:
socio-econ environment, party system, level of development, electoral rules such as compulsory, institutional structure, importance of election/ Resource model, psychological model, mobilization model, rational choice theory/Generational replacement and lowering of age, fractionalization of party system, declining group mobilization
DV:
What accounts for voter turnout variation in the aggregate/individually/why is there a decline starting in the 1990s
Outcome:
Patterns and Trends: A total of 533 elections and 106 countries are included. All democratic legislative elections (1972-2004), mean turnout 75% and stable with variation in the 3 points range. Variation in country is around 5 points. No central tendency. Turnout decline over time of 8 to 9 points. Higher in established democracies (29 countries) and slightly higher in presidential elections.
Explaining Turnout Variations across Countries: Three sets of factors have been identified: the socioeconomic environment, the institutional set-up, and the party system (Powell 1982; Blais and Dobrzynska 1998). Difference between poor and other countries (undistinguishable amongst the wealthy). Compulsory system affect turnout with a 10-15 points higher turnout (not sure if it is about the sanctions). PR and high magnitude, higher turnout /= in Latin America. Important elections and relative power of the seat at stake=higher turnout/ with a caveat (Blais 2000). Higher leverage of lower house predicts best higher turnout. Facility of voting does not produce measurable findings. Turnout appears to be higher when there are less parties in contention. “Closeness” of the results might have an effect. No real consensus on this.
Explaining the Recent Turnout Decline: three reasons for the 9 points decline since 1990 1) Generational replacement, Degree of competition of the election (Franklin). + voting age lowering is not a culprit , 2) Fractionalization in party system, 3)declining group mobilization (especially where union density has subsided). Not completely set
The Decision to Vote or not to Vote: age and education are the two most significant factors, followed by religiosity, income, and marital status (Blais 2000).
Franklin, Mark N. 2004. Voter Turnout and the Dynamics of Electoral Competition. Cambridge Univ. Press. Ch. 4&5.
Chapter 4:
Research Question:
What are the forces that induce more people to vote in some elections than in others?
- How the character of elections can affect the level of turnout.
Focus:
Case study of Malta, Switzerland, and the United States
Previous research indicates that the greatest power to cause voter turnout variation are those factors that govern the likelihood that their vote will affect an election’s outcome in ways that are meaningful to them.
Variable of focus: Executive responsiveness - the extent to which the political complexion of the executive is responsible for the choices made at the time of an election.
- Lol what the hell does this mean
Why focus on Malta and Switzerland?
- They exhibit a dramatic change in voter turnout over the past 40 years (written in 2000).
Why low turnout in the US?
Low executive responsiveness score
- Because of separation of powers
Debate over the frequency and registration
- But not that sufficient
Turnout increases when races offer clear contrasts between the policy stances of different candidates.
SOP makes it harder to figure out who is responsible and assign blame/accountability
Higher information cost
Dilutes clear accountability
Test this by measuring changes over time in the linkage between voting and its results. The idea is that if separated powers are bad for turnout, then anything that accentuates this separation should reduce turnout still further.
- Divided government as a variable
Turnout in midterm elections is correlated with turnout in the following presidential election more than the association between the previous presidential election.
If an elections is felt to be a foregone conclusion, it makes sense less people will vote.
An inventory of variables affecting electoral competition
Executive responsiveness
Margin of victory
Size of electorate
Time since previous election
Short term vs. long term effects
Chapter 5: Explaining Turnout Change in Twenty-Two Countries (more substantive chapter)
This chapter gets at the main question of: What causes turnout change? Further we can better understand the decline in turnout that has occurred in recent years.
Focus:
22 countries 1945 - 1999. ONLY look at lower house election data. Authors do not look at presidential elections or midterms.
Features that relate to the utility and costs of voting are the primary motivating forces that drive voter turnout.
Other variables include
Electoral type
Proportionality of electoral system
Extent of the franchise
Whether absentee ballots are permitted
Whether voting is compulsory
District magnitude
Election over weekend
Closeness of race
Intervals of election
Size of electorate
Size of largest party
Polarization
See page 121 for more.
Hypothesis:
We expect Signficnat effects from the following variables operationalized as short-term factors: time since the previous election, weekend voting majority status of the largest party, margin of victory of the largest party, mean margin of victory across the districts in majoritarian systems, polarization and cohesion of the party system, decisiveness of the election, and disproportionality of the electoral system
We expect significant effects from the following variables operationalized as cumulative factors: compulsory voting, absentee voting, female empowerment, extension of the franchise to eighteen year olds, size of electorate, average district magnitude, and the responsiveness of the executive to the political complexion of the legislature
We expect a significant effect of past turnout
We do not expect any features of the character of elections that can vary over time to prove significant except when operationalized as a short-term or cumulative factor.
H1 mainly involves electoral competitiveness, h2 mainly involves process of generational replacement, and h3 involves inertia.
Findings:
Absentee voting appears to be associated with falling turnout.
“Character of election” causes significant results on turnout to vary.
Female empowerment is signficant
Average district magnitude, disproportionality, weekend voting, decisiveness of the political system, polarization of party, proportion of the electorate made up of new voters, whether the government of the day was a coalition were not significant. Their role however maybe subsumed by other variables which may explain why they are not significant.
Four variables associated with electoral competition have short term effects
Size of the largest party
Margin of victory
Mean margin of victory (for majoritatarian countries)
Party cohesiveness
Four variables having to do with instiutiional arrangements have cumulative effects: compulsory voting, female empowerment, young invitations, and executive responsiveness. And size of electorate
Time since last election has effects both on new and and on established cohorts
Nickerson, David W. 2008. “Is Voting Contagious? Evidence from Two Field Experiments.” American Political Science Review 102(1): 49-57.
Bumper Sticker:
Interpersonal influence matters when it comes to voter turnout
Research Question:
How do we parse social influence in individuals’ political behavior without committing omitted or selection bias?
Research Design:
“This paper surmounts the problem of isolating and measuring interpersonal influence by analyzing two placebo-controlled experiments conducted in Denver, CO, and Minneapolis, MN, during the 2002 Congressional primaries” (49). Simultaneous canvassing to GOTV in two people household and sensibilization to recycling as a baseline. “The boost in turnout among uncontacted persons in households assigned to the GOTV condition is directly attributable to behavioral contagion, net sampling error” (49). External validity is a concern.
Literature:
Party ID fixed, interest in politics, density of network, type of network (pertaining to this study: the effect of spouse –Dasovic and Fitzgerald 2007 and voter turnout because of spouse influence- /Sparse study on spouse effect of 1 event. This is the GAP.
IV:
Contagious effect of interpersonal influence in a two-voters system
DV:
Voter turnout
Mechanism:
Social network effect on individual behaviors are difficult to measure in social science. The problem of atomism assumption: individuals establish preferences through interactions, not a vacuum. However, parsing where the influence is coming from in social network is a difficult task.
Hypothesis:
H1 The interpersonal influence from one GOTV treated person to the non-treated person in a two-voters system, will result in contagious effect on voter turnout.
Findings:
Canvassing for GOTV is an exogenous shock that works on treated individuals: +9.8% (for pooled Denver and Minneapolis) p-value< 0.01
Interpersonal influence is contagious for the second person not treated: +6% (for pooled Denver and Minneapolis) p-value < 0.1 (0.02)
Week 15: Radical Right Voting/Populism
Elçi, Ezgi. 2022. “Politics of nostalgia and populism: Evidence from Turkey.” British Journal of Political Science 52(2): 697-714.
Bumper Sticker:
Collective nostalgia has a positive relationship with populism
Research Question:
How is nostalgia used as a tool for populists?
Purpose:
Previous studies that attempted to assess the relationship between nostalgia and populism in a relatively narrow sense. The purpose of this article is to more appropriately assess the relationship between collective nostalgia and populism by situating collective nostalgia as a psychological factor that contributes to populism.
Summary/Theory/Argument:
Following the ideational approach, this study claims that populists aim to facilitate the moralistic separation between the pure people (us) and the corrupt elite (them). While constituting the boundaries of us vs. them, populists create an in-group vs. out-group identity. To this end, one of the primary tools that populists utilize is collective nostalgia. Populists offer their constituencies a golden age – a heartland where corruption, disruptions and enemies do not exist.
Elçi situates populism and collective nostalgia in the context of Turkey, where contemporary secularist and Islamic cleavages exist as a product of structures established under the Ottoman Empire. The cleavage exemplifies the ruling center (secularist elites) and the ruled periphery (the Islamic people). The ruling center adopted Kemalist beliefs - pushing the country to modernize, become secular, and overall promote nationalism. This push was the result of the fall of the Soviet Union in the 1990’s, leaving a power vacuum in the region that was filled by the Kurds . In response to this, political Islam is aggrandizing the Ottoman past as a tool for the reconstruction of “the Great Turkey” today. In this way, they are experiencing Ottoman nostalgia - a desire to return to “the golden days” and become a leader of the Islamic world. Ottoman nostalgia is much older than Kemalist nostalgia - which began to emerge in the 1990’s following increased pressure by the EU to privatize, as well as increased exposure to the IMF and World bank, which challenged the existing values of the Kemalists. This nostalgia is characterized by ‘the memory of a strong, independent, self-sufficient state and its secularist modernization politics which dominated the public sphere through the past century’.
Hypothesis:
The more nostalgic respondents are, the more populist attitudes they will express, because nostalgia creates a ‘pure people vs. corrupt elites’ duality.
Respondents in the nostalgia treatment groups should be more populist than those in the control group in the experimental setting.
The effect of the Ottoman nostalgia treatment on populist attitudes should be greater than the Kemalist nostalgia stimulus in the experimental setting.
Findings:
Collective nostalgia has a significantly positive relationship with populist attitudes even after control for various independent variables - such as religiosity, partisanship, satisfaction with life and Euroscepticism
Ottoman nostalgia increases populist attitudes
Kemalist nostalgia has a weak direct effect on attitude that disappears when party preference is controlled for
Method:
Uses a representative survey (n=1,954) and experimental datasets
the survey tests the link between individuals’ predisposition to nostalgia and populist attitudes (H1)
DV:Populist beliefs
- constructed from four survey items from previous research that Elçi aggregated into an index ranging from 0 (least agreement) to 100 (most agreement)
IV: Nostalgia
- Constructed from four different survey items that seek to measure the importance of past values, past experiences, old tastes, and the country’s glorious past
Controls:
Three sets of IVs to control for the relationship between populism and nostalgia
support for EU membership, satisfaction with democracy, economic conditions, and life, and interpersonal trust questions
Alevi, Kurdish and religiosity, where the cross-cutting cleavages in Turkish society occur.
Partisanship, sex, age, education, income, urban residency.
Created 10 different models to control for the effect of nostalgia with party preference and satisfaction with life, democracy, and economic conditions.
Also performed an experimental analysis
created a between-group experimental design in which two groups received different types of nostalgic messages
These were Ottoman and Kemalist
Also used a control group that DID NOT receive any stimulus
Data was collected using convenience sampling - respondents were recruited through Facebook and Instagram ads using Qualtrics survey tool
N = 911
Were asked a series of warmup questions - such as satisfaction with democracy, lives, and economic conditions
Randomly assigned them to groups
Introduced experimental vignettes
Ottoman and Kemalist groups were presented with a message priming them to respond to texts about history of Turkey
Control group did not receive any message
tested the effect of nostalgia treatments on populist attitudes by building a populism index with five items taken from Akkerman, Mudde and Zaslove (2014).
summed all items and built a scale between 0 and 100, where 100 indicates higher populist attitudes
Definitions:
Populism
(Mudde, 2007) a thin-centered ideology that considers society to be ultimately separated into to homogenous and antagonistic groups:
- the pure people versus the corrupt elite
Collective Nostalgia
- (Wildschut et al. 2014) the nostalgic reverie that is contingent upon thinking of oneself in terms of a particular social identity or as a member of a particular group and concerns events or objects related to it
Cleavages
- (Somer & McCoy, 2019) formative rifts that ’either emerged or could not be resolved during the formation of nation-states, or, sometimes during fundamental re-formulations of states such as during transitions from communism to capitalism, or authoritarian to democratic regime
General Notes:
Turkey’s populist Justice and Development Party (Adalet ve Kalkınma Partisi, AKP) exploits nostalgic rhetoric to dominate the country’s politics.
- emphasize the glorious days of the Ottoman and Seljukian empires
Populists frequently emphasize that the elites hijacked the people’s will long ago, and they promise to return power to the people.
- According to this logic, back in the good old days corrupt elites were not powerful enough to abuse the authentic people.
According to populists, the people’s will is the cornerstone of politics
Many scholars agree that populism appears as a backlash to a sense of severe crisis (Rooduijn 2014; Taggart 2004) or discontent (Spruyt, Keppens and Van Droogenbroeck 2016).
This sense of extreme crisis paves the way for raising concerns about the present conditions, which is a breeding ground for populism (Akkerman, Mudde and Zaslove 2014).
Populists blame the establishment for the decline in the people’s economic, political and living standards (Rooduijn, van der Brug and de Lange 2017).
Populism can also be generated by unsolved, long-lasting and cross-cutting political cleavages within a society. Somer and McCoy (2019, 8) define these cleavages as formative rifts that ’either emerged or could not be resolved during the formation of nation-states, or, sometimes during fundamental re-formulations of states such as during transitions from communism to capitalism, or authoritarian to democratic regime
Nostalgia is a yearning for the past
According to Strauth and Turner (1988) it has four component parts
First, ‘there is the view of history as decline and loss, being a departure from some golden age of “homefulness”’.
Second, is the problem that there exists ‘a sense of the loss of wholeness and moral certainty’.
- At this point, ‘history is seen to be a collapse of values which had once provided the unity of social relations and personal experience’.
The third is related to ‘the loss of individual autonomy and the collapse of genuine social relationships’.
Last but not least, nostalgia is ‘the sense of a loss of simplicity, spontaneity, and authenticity’
Nostalgia, or the way we remember our past, exacerbates in-group vs. out-group distinctions (Martinovic et al. 2018).
Nostalgia also strengthens shared social identity and distinguishes the in-group from other groups (Brown and Humphreys 2002; Wildschut et al. 2014).
The rise of populism is closely related to ‘acute despair at the present moment and a memory of a previous golden age’.
The golden age corresponds to the heartland in populist literature.
Coined by Taggart (2004, 278), ‘the heartland is a construction of the good life derived retrospectively from a romanticized conception of life as it has been lived’.
It involves returning to the pre-lapsarian world, a Golden age before a catastrophic lapse or fall: in the post-lapsarian era, individuals feel lacking, deficient or oppressed (Tannock 1995).
In Turkey, secularists and Islamist cleavages exist
The secularists can be thought of as the elites and appear to be supported by the left
- they have dominated Turkish politics and society as guardians of the Kemalist values
The Islamist’s are the people, representing the ruled and appear to be supported by the right (Çarkoğlu 2012; Çarkoğlu and Hinich 2006).
Expectations that impacted Control variable selection:
The author expects that the more dissatisfied respondents are with their lives in general, subjective economic conditions and democracy, the more populist attitudes they will have.
Religiosity plays a pivotal role in explaining the party preferences of the Turkish constituency and is a key independent variable for explaining the center–periphery cleavage.
- Therefore expects more religious respondents to display more populist attitudes.
Expect Alevi respondents to have less populist attitudes because they are more supportive of secularism.
Expects that Kurdish respondents will have more populist attitudes because they are more critical of the Kemalist establishment.
The Peoples’ Democratic Party (Halkların Demokratik Partisi, HDP), as a radical democratic pro-Kurdish party, should also display more populist attitudes
expect CHP and Nationalist Action Party (Milliyetçi Hareket Partisi, MHP) voters to have less populist attitudes since they represent the status quo.
Fitzgerald, Jennifer. 2018. Close to Home: Local Ties and Voting Radical Right in Europe. Cambridge University Press. Chapters TBD.
Chapter 1:
Research Question:
Why do people vote for radical right parties? Why do certain people at certain times in certain places decide that a radical right party or candidate merits their electoral support?
Focus:
Europe, North American, Oceania
- Mainly Switzerland and France
Literature insights:
Originally, social group based voting was powerful and pervasive. The left had unions and the right had churches; these were stabilizing forces.
However, as membership in unions and churches and their attendant social groups wanes, support for mainstream left and right parties becomes less socially rooted in a traditional sense and less habitual.
- Instead of approaching elections from particular social positions, people now make choices at the polls that are motivated by attitudes on specific policy issues and attraction to particular political leaders.
Localist Theory of Radical Right Voting: an account of unconventional electoral behavior that is motivated by people’s feelings of attachment to their local communities
Main Argument:
“I argue that those individuals with the strongest sense of belonging to their localities find the programs of radical right parties particularly appealing.”
All politics is local - Tip O’Neill
Local attachments underpin and motivate radical right support
Localism:
Small scale communities can offer a sense of belonging and a sense of place; research in psychology bears this out.
Globalization has changed things.
As globalism has increased, the importance of the local has grown in response.
“Modern life has not erased the importance of place…It may have, instead, increased the need for people to draw boundaries, to more crisply define their geographic community…and to behave in ways that signal their place-related identities…People are often proud of where they are from, and they continue to want you to know it. (Cramer 2016: 240, fn. 12)
Globalization pushes people to invest reflexively in their local areas, it also threatens to undermine what makes each locality special. Pg 6
Eric Hobsbawm: The impersonalizing forces of globalization push people to invent mental connections to social groups, thereby reinforcing the rise of identity politics.
What is the typical right winger?
MAN
Low socio-economic status
Typically holds negative view of modern developments
Immigration, outsiders ruining “the way it was”
- Trad dudes.
Interesting insights:
High Social Capital negates the typical right winger.
“Straddling the individual-aggregate divide are accounts informed by theorist of social capital; the argument is that individuals who invest in social capital (through the participation in civil society) and those communities rich in social capital will not find the radical right particularly appealing” (Coffe et al. 2007)
Findings:
I find that today’s passion for all things local and localities’ enhanced political salience have contributed to the growth of radical right parties.
Radical right does best when locality is politically salient.
Local tues are most politically relevant when and where the locality has significant authority and autonomy, when and where the locality has recently lost substantial power, and when and where local elections are temporally proximal to national elections.
Mudde, Cas, and Christóbol Rovira Kaltwasser. 2013. “Exclusionary vs. Inclusionary Populism: Comparing Contemporary Europe and Latin America.” Government and Opposition 48(2): 147-174.
This is not an empirical paper and it’s kind of like a case study (sort of).
Bumper Sticker:
Subtypes of populism have regional similarities; Latin American populism is generally inclusive in nature while European populism is generally exclusive.
Data:
Broad patterns of populism with more focused attention on France, Austria, Bolivia, and Venezuela
General Notes:
Rise in interest in studying populism and its relationship with democracy
One key aspect: is populism exclusive, inclusive, or both?
Findings largely regionally determined; LA inclusive while Europe exclusive
Few cross-regional studies
To overcome conceptual confusion and regional isolation, this article investigates whether populism is exclusive or inclusive (or both) cross-regionally and by consistently using one definition of populism
4 case studies 1990-2010: Haider and Austrian Freedom Party (FPÖ), Le Pen and French National Front (FN), Morales and Bolivian Movement for Socialism (MAS), and Chávez and United Socialist Party of Venezuela (PSUV)
3 dimensions of inclusion/exclusion: material, symbolic, and political
- 2 factors crucial to understanding regional patterns:
The way populist actors define who belongs to ‘the people’ vis-à-vis ‘the elite’
The ideological features attached to the particular populist ideology of the actors
- BOTH share a problematic relationship w/liberal democracy
Populism defined:
Minimalist definition of populism: a thin-centered ideology that considers society to be ultimately separated into two homogenous and antagonistic groups, “the pure people” versus “the corrupt elite”, and which argues that politics should be an expression of the general will of the people.
Key elements of the concept:
Theoretical and empirical perspective
Thin-centered ideology = a particular set of ideas that is limited in ambition and scope; highly context-dependent
3 core concepts:
The pure people
The corrupt elite
The general will
- Carries idea that all individuals of a given community are able to unify their wills with the aim of proclaiming popular sovereignty as the only legitimate source of political power
Advantages of the concept:
Good concept-building characterized by presenting a definition based on necessary and sufficient conditions and identifying its negative pole: elitism and pluralism
Elitism = the people are dishonest and vulgar while the elite are superior in cultural, intellectual, and moral terms
Pluralism = societies are composed of several social groups with different ideas and interests; favors many centers of powers and maintains that politics should reflect the preferences of as many groups as possible through compromise and consensus
Populism has a ‘chameleon character’ – it can be left-wing or right-wing, organized in top-down or bottom-up fashion, rely on strong leaders or even be leaderless
Thus, subtypes of populism should be the starting point for analysis
Since populism is an ideology rather than a political strategy, it is linked to both supply-side and demand-side factors
Case selection
Relies on analysis of prototypical cases so they can offer tentative conclusions
European populism fairly new (? true?)
Features nativism, populism, and authoritarianism
“Marriage of convenience” with the radical right in Europe
Latin America has a rich tradition of populist leaders, movements, and parties
3 ‘waves of populism’ in Latin America:
Classic populism of 1940s and 1960s
Neoliberal populism during 1990s
Radical leftist populism since 2000s
Focus is on both leaders and parties
Inclusion vs. Exclusion?
Framework comes from recent (2010) study of the political right in Israel
The Material Dimension – distribution of state resources, both monetary and non-monetary, to specific groups in society
Exclusion – groups specifically excluded from access to state resources (jobs or welfare)
Inclusion – groups specifically targeted to receive (more) state resources, sometimes to overcome long-established discrimination
Latin America: Chávez and Morales have pushed policies to promote quality of life improvements for weak socioeconomic groups
Social missions (misiones sociales)
Health care programs, expansion of primary education, distribution of subsidized food and housing provision services
Morales – cash transfer programs to school-aged children and improvement of old age pension
Financed by gas an oil and new political economy of development
Exclusion of economic establishment
Europe: richer than LA, therefore instead of establishing welfare state they are focused on protecting it from outside forces (notably immigrants); focus in on exclusion of outgroups
Welfare chauvinism – fairly generous welfare state generally supported for the ‘own people’ but not for ‘aliens’ (immigrants, refugees, or Roma)
Français d’abord (French first)
The Political Dimension – refers to political participation and public contestation
Exclusion – specific groups prevented from participating (fully) in the democratic system
Inclusion – specifically targets certain groups to increase their participation and representation
LA: radical democracy (or revolutionary or real); criticize elitist character of LA democracies and plead for broader political participation
Strengthening the ‘voice of the voiceless’
Venezuelan PSUV promotes formation of a protagonist and participatory democracy based on plebiscitary mechanisms and communal councils
Bolivarian Circles (’círculos bolivarianos) = groups of 8-10 people seeking to engage in consciousness raising and community projects at the grassroots level
Bolivian MAS supports new constitution aimed at political participation through direct democratic channels
Ideology of Americanismo is an important element in defense of the model of radical democracy and in the attack on ‘foreign’ forms of political rule
Political participation has increased but rules of public contestation have been undermined
Europe: want democracy to be more responsive to natives and promote exclusion of non-natives
Populist parties attract higher levels of blue-collar workers
More young and new reps
Vehemently oppose extending political rights to ‘aliens’
The Symbolic Dimension – least tangible; alludes to setting the boundaries of ‘the people’ and, ex negativo, ‘the elite’
“When populists define ‘the people,’ in their rhetoric and symbols without referring to (characteristics and values of) certain groups, the latter are symbolically excluded (for example, Roma in Eastern Europe)” (164).
When groups are linked to the elite they are explicitly excluded from ‘the people’
Off, Gefjon. 2023. “Gender equality salience, backlash and radical right voting in the gender-equal context of Sweden.” West European Politics 46(3): 451-476.
Bumper Sticker:
Issue salience does matter.
Research Question:
In an otherwise egalitarian society, under which conditions do gender values play a role in right-wing extremism vote?
Literature:
Gender values and cultural backlash (Norris and Inglehart, 2019 = generational change; Burns and Gallagher, 2010; Spierings, 2020), cultural backlash other issues: immigration + novelty of progressive gender values with anti-immigration (Lancaster, 2022) -> countering Muslim immigration. Issue salience = when does the backlash occurs (Adams, 1997; Dahlstrom and Esaiasson, 2013; Wojcieszak, 2018; Bishin, 2016; Belanger and Meguid, 2008; Dennison, 2020),
Research Design:
A first difference correlational (not causal) analysis of the 2014 and 2018 Sweden elections. Conditional argument placing issue salience, such as liberal gender values, and resulting backlash as a right-wing extremism vote predictor. Difference in exit poles concerning the issue, gender-related Google searches (with Google trends analysis). Using the SNES for survey questions on gender issues and voting preference.
Hypothesis:
Gender value gap increases between PRR voters and other voters when gender issues are salient = gender attitudes indicators (y) ~ voting for SD (X1) * year dummy (X2)
Conservative gender values are positively related to PRR voting when gender issues are salient = voting for SD (y) ~ on gender attitudes indicators (Xs)/Logistic regression
Mechanism:
Issue salience triggers a cultural backlash: provide more information for the individual on the issue and will provoke a certain type of vote.
Findings:
Having conservative attitudes towards gender issues predicted a 20% probability to vote for SD (more than doubling the prediction between 2014-2018)
SD voters hold consistently less progressive views on gender issues
This trend increase d between 2014 and 2018 (relating to salience)/ Other voters went the other direction and increased support for progressive measures
Gap increased more for power distribution than LGBTQ questions
Citation
@online{neilon2024,
author = {Neilon, Stone},
title = {Comparative {Behavior}},
date = {2024-05-15},
url = {https://stoneneilon.github.io/notes/Comparative_Behavior/},
langid = {en}
}
***Social Capital v. Localism***
So like if you have good thoughts about your communities you will vote far right but if you’re very involved with community you won’t
Having very positive sentiment toward the locality and the people in it can make the radical right appealing.
In contrast, route engagement in community life wards off the appeals of these parties; when people invest their time and energy into participating in civil society and neighborhood life, the radical right is not so enticing an option.
When people avoid routine social and organizational activity, but still feel very positively tied to their local communities, they are powerfully primed to consider radical right programs alluring.